[Previous
Page]
-XIV-
THE FAMOUS TWENTY-EIGHT.
ROCHDALE is a town which has been in its time
equally distinguished for poverty and pluck. The distress and
discontent which existed there before the days of the Reform Bill of 1832
are, happily, no longer, even in the recollection of the present
generation of inhabitants, who have ceased to be reminded of it in their
daily personal experience.
In the old hungry Corn Law days, from 1826 to 1830, things
went ill with the working classes of Rochdale. At public meetings of
working people in the town statements were made of lowness of wages and
domestic wretchedness, which would be deemed incredible now.
Delegates were sent to neighbouring towns to report upon their condition,
and deplorable stories they told. No one would imagine that such
persona had the capacity of co-operation in them, or that it was in the
power of any industrial device to do them substantial service. The
creditable thing is that Rochdale men, though in desperate circumstances,
were not wanting in public spirit. They had constables who were not
pleasant-minded persons and were guilty of some offensive official
irregularities, and though they had the power of retaliation on those of
the workmen who objected to such proceedings, the weavers resolved to
bring them to account, and out of their scanty means subscribed enough to
"have the law" upon them, and succeeded. The old parish records
contain, no doubt, particulars of the affair. Mr. Francis Place
preserved the only published account of it I have seen. The
creditable incident is worth recalling. Scores of local officials,
magistrates included, have elsewhere "gone wrong" since that day, without
being called to account, as was done by the unappeasable weavers of
Rochdale. Twenty years have now nearly elapsed since the first part
of this history appeared. The two dozen and four adventurous
operatives who began the Store in Toad Lane, have come to be spoken of as
the "famous twenty-eight." Most of them are now gathered to their
fathers, and the public will be willing to hear final details of them.
A correspondent to whom I have been heretofore indebted for
information says that "in a recent conversation with a member of the
Rochdale Educational Committee, he was informed that the old shop in Toad
Lane, in which the Pioneers commenced business, was known as 'The
Pioneers' Store' for years before it was occupied by them, in consequence
of being used as a storeroom for the Pioneer regiment, stationed in
Rochdale, before the barracks were removed to Bury. The place behind
the shop is still known as Barracks' Yard, and there may be some truth in
this. If so, it may be that the Pioneers took their name from that
circumstance, or it may be a more coincidence."
My belief is that this was merely a coincidence. In
social and trade union literature before that date, there were
publications bearing the name of the Pioneer, and pioneering was in the
mind of the early Socialists; it was a common ambition amongst them to be
going forward and doing something. The fact, however, is worth
recording, as it has never before been mentioned.
In the minds of many outsiders, Chartists and the
co-operators were so mixed together in the rise of co-operation in
Rochdale, that only time and testimony can separate them, and satisfy
every one to whom the credit of the movement was really owing. There
never was a doubt entertained among persons living on the spot, or
acquainted with the facts, that the Socialists were the persons who first
thought of starting co-operation, who counselled it, who originated it and
organised it, kept it going, and carried it out. The fact is, the
Chartists were impediments in the way of it. They were the most
troublesome opponents the co-operators had to contend with. The
Chartists were opposed to co-operation. They took little interest in it. They treated as apostates those who did. For a long time they did not
understand it, and when they did they distrusted it. But sixteen years
after, when co-operation had succeeded and become a thing of pride and
repute, they made attempts to prove they were the persons who commenced
it. Many years after cooperation acquired notice and power, their able and
cultivated leader, Mr. Ernest Jones, opposed it in a public discussion at Padiham about 1851 with Mr. Lloyd Jones. It has been the fate of other
movements than that of co-operation to be strenuously opposed throughout
all its struggling days, and then to be claimed by its greatest
adversaries as their own discovery and as being the cause which they had
advocated and befriended. It is always a good sign when these pretensions
are advanced by opponents, since it shows that the principle has
triumphed, and its most strenuous adversaries are covetous of the honour
of being associated with it. But it is the business of history to discern
to whom the credit of origination belongs, and give it to whom it is due.
In 1861, the Chartist claim was put forward in the
Rochdale Spectator with confident pertinacity by Ambrose Tomlinson. A
Chartist Society existed in Rochdale in 1843. Mr. Tomlinson denied that
the co-operative movement grew out of the flannel weavers' strike of
1843-4. He said that it commenced with the Chartist Society, who met in
Mill Street, the fact being the Mill Street Chartists opposed the movement
in its infancy, and, because several of their members joined the Society
formed under the name of the Equitable Pioneers, they were denounced by
their Chartist brethren as "deserters." In those days the doctrine was—"The Charter, the whole Charter, and nothing but the Charter." These oft-repeated phrases still ring in the ears of those who mingled in working-class movements of those times. To co-operators, to advocates of the
Ten Hours Bill, to Corn Law repealers—three separate parties who then
occupied public attention—the Chartists everywhere said—"If you will not
help us to get what we want, we will prevent you getting anything." And
they did it as far as they were
able. The Chartists did not succeed in carrying their measure by
that unfriendly policy, and did not deserve to succeed. Each movement has
a right to do the best for itself, but when it seeks to frustrate the
success of those going in the same direction in order that it may win
first, it merely helps the common enemy of all, and enables it to be said
derisively—"See how these Reformers are fighting amongst themselves."
Mr. Ambrose Tomlinson, an active Rochdale Chartist of those days, gives an
account of what occurred among his comrades, in words nearly as follows:—"The co-operators, the few originators of the movement, who were all
Chartists, became so enamoured of co-operation, that they nurtured it in
one corner of Mill Street Chartist room. The Chartist council held their
meetings in the opposite corner of the same room; but on many successive
occasions the Chartist council corner became very thin of attenders. At
this juncture those of the Chartists who had attended the council meetings
reproached the Chartist co-operators who had resolved to attend the
co-operative meetings, and neglect Chartist business. The few sturdy
co-operators took umbrage, and resolved to meet together at the Labour and
Health beer-house, kept by Mr. Tweedale at that time, not one hundred
yards from the
Chartist room in Mill Street. The use of that room at the Labour and
Health was secured by Ann Tweedale, a female co-operator,
who was sister to the landlord. She afterwards became the wife of Benjamin Standring, inducing him to become a co-operator soon
after their marriage. The co-operators met there for only a very few weeks
before they joined the Chartists at their place of meeting
again. They again became attached as friends, when the Chartists took the
Socialists' room from the Socialists, at the time of the
failure of the Harmony Hall scheme. The co-operators went with the
Chartists from Mill Street Chartist room to the room situate at the top of
Yorkshire Street. The co-operators remained with the Chartists until the
September following. During that time they were contriving plans for the
future of co-operation, drawing up rules, making preparations for
commencing; then they resolved to look out for more suitable premises for
carrying on business, when they got possession of the building in Toad
Lane, formerly known as Bethel School Room." [42]
One is glad to hear again of the beer-house with the pretty name of "Labour and Health." But let us hope that the attendance was not too
enthusiastic there—because when that is the case "labour" sometimes
loses its "health" in those quarters. No doubt the
Chartist opposition to the early Pioneers in Rochdale seems a small thing
in 1877, now the Pioneers have grown to many thousands and the Chartists
have become nearly extinct—but it was a very different thing in 1844 and
long afterwards, when the Chartists were ten or twenty times as numerous
as the Socialists. Every earnest party in which principles are masters of
its leaders, instead of leaders being masters of their principles, has its
mad days when its advocates think
their principles should take precedence of all others. Indeed, they
sometimes contend that all other principles are injurious. Sanity is known
by seeing what your place is and working in it.
The Socialist flannel weavers, after their unsuccessful strike, founded
the Equitable Pioneers' Society, and commenced subscribing practically to
create a fund with which to begin a small provision store. At first they
met where the weavers had done, in the Bethel
School Room, Toad Lane. Ultimately their meetings were removed to the
Social Institution, top of Yorkshire Street, and the Equitable
Pioneers' Society dates its establishment from this place. Mr. John Holt,
who had been the treasurer at Mill Street, became the treasurer of the
Store Society, and continued to hold that office until shortly
before his decease. The rules of the Equitable Pioneers' Society were
drawn up at the Social Institution, and the older heads among the
Socialists were those who framed them and organised the Society. Mr.
Tomlinson (February, 1861) handed to the Editor of the Rochdale Spectator
the book of the Society existing immediately before the Equitable
Pioneers' Association was formed. The names it contained are worth
preserving for historical reference:—
"George Morton, Mount Pleasant; and then follow Charles Ratcliffe, Regent
Street; Robert Whitehead, John Dawson, Richard Farmer, Richard Brierley,
Thomas Kershaw, Mary Bromley, Mount Pleasant; Ann Tweedale, Mount Pleasant; Charles Holroyd, Lower Fold; Samuel Shore, Healey; John Cain, Richard
Street; Benjamin Rudman, Shawclough; Abner Riley, Calder Brow; Abraham
Birtwistle, Water Street; Fred. Greenwood, Moss; Miles Ashworth, Spotland Bridge; James Nutall, Bank Side; Samuel Ashworth, Spotland
Bridge; John Holt, Shawclough."
The next matter in the book is the list of parties who received the money
from Mr. George Howe, watchmaker, Walk, when he refused to continue
secretary. The names are the same as those above. The next account is that
in which Mr. Alderman Livsey receives as treasurer of the co-operators
various sums, amounting in the whole to £8 13s. 6d. This money was
received by Mr. Livsey on the 7th February, 1843.
The capital with which the Pioneer Society first commenced business was,
as everybody knows now, £28; and, by coincidence, the number of members
which commenced the Society was also 28.
In 1865, 21 years after the formation of the Store, the then survivors, 13 in number, were prevailed upon by Mr. Smithies to meet together
and be photographed in a group, for the gratification of friends of the
great Store. [43] For the convenience of readers
who may meet with the group, I give here the following description of the
Pioneers in it, as told me by William Cooper, retaining his own language,
not devoid of force and individuality:—
"A short sketch of the thirteen persons who were amongst the early members
of the Rochdale Equitable Pioneers' Society, now on a photograph taken at
the latter end of the year 1865.
"The photograph being placed before you, commence at the left hand with
those sitting in the front.
|
Thirteen of the original Rochdale Pioneers,
photographed in 1865. |
"No. 1. James Standring, at the time of the Society's formation a flannel
weaver by trade; an Owenite or Social Reformer; was secretary in Rochdale
for the Ten Hours Factory Act agitation. When the flannel weavers turned
out in 1843-4 for an advance of wages, and failed in accomplishing their
object, he procured a copy of the Friendly Societies Acts, to see whether
the remnant of the union amongst the weavers could take advantage of its
provisions to form manufacturing or other associations for their
self-employment, protection, and benefit.
"No. 2. John Bent, tailor by trade, belonged to the Socialist body, was
one of the first auditors of the Society.
"No. 3. James Smithies, wool-sorter and book-keeper, a Social Reformer,
was one of the first directors. Has at various times held office as
president, secretary, trustee, and director in the Society. Has always
laboured to promote the spread of co-operation, and to preserve in it the
just and fraternal spirit.
|
William Cooper, Charles Howarth and John Smithies |
"No. 4. Charles Howarth, a warper in a cotton mill by trade, belonged to
the Socialist body. Was one of the first trustees of the
Rochdale Equitable Pioneers' Society. He mostly drew up the rules by which
the Society was to be governed, and proposed that the rule or principle of
dividing profits on purchases in proportion to each
member's trade, should be adopted. He has at sundry periods held
office on the committee as secretary. During the Ten Hours Bill agitation
he was one of the delegates who went to London to confer with members of
Parliament and watch the Bill while before the
House of Commons. Being a mill worker, he was in close contact with the
employers, some of whom had no liking for legislation as
between them and their employees. On one occasion he was called into the
office by his employers, and they made a proposal something in this way:—He must remain in the office, and they would send for the hands one by
one out of the mill, and put the question to them whether they wanted the
Ten Hours Bill, with a reduction in wages
corresponding with the shorter time. By this means they said it could be
ascertained whether a majority of their workpeople were in
favour or against the Ten Flours Factory Act. Charles Howarth agreed so to
do, providing they would consent first for him to have a meeting with the
hands in one of the rooms of the mill, to explain
and address them on the subject. The employers did not assent to this, so
there was no meeting and no calling of the workpeople into the office.
"No. 5. David Brooks, a block printer by trade; a Chartist in politics. Was the first appointed purchaser of goods for the Society. He was an
honest enthusiast, who spared neither time, labour, nor means to promote
the success of the Society.
"No. 6. Benjamin Rudman, a flannel weaver by trade; a Chartist in
politics. A man of few words, but a steady supporter of the society.
"No. 7. John Scrowcroft, hawker by trade; nothing in politics; a
Swedenborgian in religion. In the early days of the Society members often
came to the Store and had conversations. Politics, religion, or other
subjects, were at times talked over, and occasionally there would be a
night set apart—not a business meeting of the Society—by those members
who choose to attend, to debate on a stated
question. Of course, religion was sometimes the topic for the evening. Some of the members who were religious thought it a sin to debate
their faith, and they proposed to prohibit such matters being open to
criticism; but John Scrowcroft was thoroughly sincere in his religion,
and said it was as much a proper subject for debate as any
other question. Indeed, he was certain his was the true faith, and the
more religion was examined and discussed the greater number
would come to believe it. The motion to 'muzzle did not get itself
carried.'
"Commencing at the left with those standing in back:—
"No. 8. James Manock, flannel weaver by trade; Chartist in politics; has
served on the committee at various times as trustee, director.
"No. 9. John Collier, engineer by trade; a Socialist. Has been
a committee-man of the Society several times. He speaks in the broad
Lancashire style, and no wonder, as he is a great-grandson of the famous
John Collier ('Tim Bobbin'), of Milnrow, near Rochdale, who wrote books in
verse and prose in the years 1744 and 1750 in Lancashire dialect, full of
wit and droll humour, in which the 'Witch' and the 'Parson' come in for a
fair share of satire. John Collier ('Tim Bobbin') was buried in
Rochdale Old Churchyard, 1786, with the following epitaph on his
gravestone, said to have been composed by himself about ten minutes before
he died:—
"Here lies John, and with him Mary,
Cheek by jowl and never vary;
No wonder
that they so agree,
John wants no punch, and Moll no tea."' [44] |
"No. 10. Samuel Ashworth, flannel weaver by trade; Chartist in politics. Was appointed the first salesman in the Store.
"No. 11. William Cooper, flannel weaver by trade; a member of the
Socialist body. Was appointed the first cashier in the Store.
"No. 12. James Tweedale, a clogger by trade; a Socialist. Was one of the
first directors in the Society.
"No. 13. Joseph Smith, woolsorter by trade; a Social Reformer. Was
appointed one of the first auditors of the Society."
Mr Cooper on another occasion, with that sense of
justice always a pleasant feature in him, desired me to remark that the
photograph does not give all the persons then living in Rochdale who were
among the early members of the Rochdale Equitable Pioneers' Society.
Partly by oversight and partly by misunderstanding three are left out:—
"Miles Ashworth, flannel weaver by trade; Chartist in politics. Was the
first president of the Society."
"James Maden, flannel weaver by trade, teetotaler; nothing in particular
in politics or religion."
"John Kershaw, warehouseman by trade; Swedenborgian and half Chartist."
Mr. James Smithies, no less considerate and
conservative of the repute of co-operative workers, sent me at my request
the following notice of David Brooks, No. 5 of the series explained by Mr.
Cooper:—
"Mr. David Brooks, a block printer by trade, whose name has never been
mentioned in connection with the Rochdale Co-operative Society in its
earliest stages of existence, rendered services of no mean order. He was
the first purchaser appointed by the Society, an office which required
much care and ability, besides being the butt at
which the scorn and contempt of the shopkeepers was directed. He never
flinched from the post assigned to him, although the foreman of the works
at which he was employed was a shopkeeper; yet he still served the Store
with a fidelity rarely, if ever, surpassed by a true believer in the
emancipation of the working classes by their own
exertions. He frequently left his own employment, at which he could then
earn 7s. to 8s. per day, to work for love of the cause, until the Society
could afford to pay him something like 3d. per hour for his
labour. For four to five years he was superintendent and purchaser. Although, like many a flower, 'born to blush unseen,' his services
have never been acknowledged; or rather say, until the present panic,
which almost annihilated the block printing business, brought the old boy
so low in his finances that a notice was given that an application would
be brought before the quarterly meeting to make him a present of ten
pounds, to assist him to stave off his enemy, poverty; but a generous
committee did better, they found him employment at one of the Branch
Stores, where he was numbered among the servants of the Society, contented
to serve where he once commanded."
Mr. Smithies does not mention that it was he who made the honourable
motion which brought acknowledgment and succour to Mr. Brooks in the day
of his decay of means and power.
It would be well were Mr. Walter Morrison's suggestion acted on, and the
old Toad Lane Store purchased by the Pioneers, and held in its old Store
state, as a memorial of the early days of their career, and used as a
news-room: and portraits, so far as can now be done, painted of the old
Pioneers, and preserved in the hall of the old Toad Lane Store. This would
be a graceful memorial, quite in the power of the great Society to
preserve, and it would have infinite interest a century hence to all
visitors from afar and students of the science of
co-operative economy. From the public spirit of the Pioneers, it may come
to pass, as it is in the power of the Store, to remain, if it
chooses, the Pioneer Store of the great movement. Let us hope that the
wealthy and historic Society which has grown out of Toad Lane will
endeavour to possess and preserve in its original state the humble
building in which the organisation of Co-operation was commenced. One of the Oldham Societies has a "conversation room;" the lower
part of the Toad Lane building might serve that purpose, where questions
might be continually debated, and the business meeting of the Society
elsewhere would be greatly facilitated by the members being personally
informed of the questions to be decided. Other parts of the building might
contain the reference library, which business requires to be separate from
the great library at the central stores.
The following are the names of the original
Twenty-Eight:—
James Smithies. |
John Scrowcroft. |
Charles Howarth. |
John Hill. |
William Cooper. |
John Holt. |
David Brooks. |
James Standring. |
John Collier. |
James Manock. |
Samuel Ashworth. |
Joseph Smith. |
Miles Ashworth. |
William Taylor. |
William Mallalieu. |
Robert Taylor. |
George Healey. |
Benjamin Rudmam. |
James Daly. |
James Wilkinson. |
James Tweedale. |
John Garside. |
Samuel Tweedale. |
John Bent. |
John Kershaw. |
Ann Tweedale. |
James Maden. |
James Bamford. |
No complete list has been given before of the "original Twentyeight." One
list wanted four names—they are given above. Mr. George Adcroft,
president of the Store, in 1847, three years after its formation, has gone
with me over the names of all the early members, and has decided that
James Wilkinson, shoemaker, was one; John Garside, cabinetmaker, was
another; George Healey, hatter, was the third; and Samuel Tweedale was the
fourth, belonging to the "Twenty-eight." There were two Tweedales among
them, James and Samuel. James was a clogger, and lived at the
top of Wardleworth Brow, and kept a cloggers shop there. Samuel
Tweedale was a weaver at King's the quaker, Oldham Road. Samuel
gave the first little lecture they had in the Toad Lane Store. It
was on "Morals in their relations to every day life." It was on a Sunday
night. He was considered the "talking man" of the Store. He afterwards
went to Australia. Among the "Twenty-eight" there were eight Jameses and
seven Johns.
-XV-
LEGAL IMPEDIMENTS TO ECONOMY.
WHEN the Rochdale Society began, and for many years
subsequent, such associations were not recognised by law. The
members had no defined rights, and were under unlimited responsibility:
yet they were incompetent to deal with outsiders, or even with themselves.
Indeed, the cash box might disappear with impunity. The Society
could not hold land above a small quantity; members could only hold a very
limited sum in the funds even after the law did begin to befriend them:
nor could they devote their savings to self education. Indeed, it
would take pages to explain all the legal disabilities then existing.
By whose generous exertions all this came to be altered is related
elsewhere. [45]
Nobody understood better or cared more for the legal position
of co-operation than the Rochdale Pioneers. The townsmen who had Mr.
Thos. Livsey for an alderman, Mr. Cobden for a member, and Mr. Bright for
a neighbour, ought to be in advance of other towns, and they were.
The Pioneers, assisted by eminent friends of social reform in London, Mr.
E. V. Neale, Mr. Thos. Hughes, Mr. F. J. Furnivall, and Mr. J. M. Ludlow,
procured the necessary amendment of the law; and when it was done, they
had the grace to distinguish who had served them and to place on record
their thanks to each. On Christmas Day, 1862, an annual conference
of 100 delegates from the co-operative societies of Lancashire and the
neighbouring counties was held in Oldham. Seventy-five societies
were represented. Mr. Abraham Greenwood, of Rochdale, presided.
Mr. William Cooper of Rochdale, secretary of the conference committee,
stated that when the previous conference met at Rochdale, on the 25th of
December, 1861, the Hon. Robert A. Slaney, M.P., who had, up to that time,
had the charge of their Bill in the House of Commons, was on the
Continent, owing to failing health. The committee (on the approval
of Mr. Slaney and the advice of Mr. Bright, who accompanied a deputation
for that purpose) solicited the Government to bring in the Bill.
They declined to bring it in as a Government measure, but intimated that
they should not oppose it if it was brought in by a private member.
Mr. Bright then recommended the committee to solicit Mr. Estcourt to
introduce the Bill to Consolidate and Amend the Industrial and Provident
Societies Acts. He cordially took charge of the Bill in the Commons,
and the Hon. Robert A. Slaney, M. P. (who, we regret to say, soon after
died), arrived just in time to second the Bill in its first reading.
The committee sent three separate deputations to London, at various stages
of the Bill while before Parliament, to explain it and interest Members in
its favour. Besides these special deputations, their tried friend,
Mr. E. V. Neale, living in the neighbourhood of London, was at call to act
on behalf of the committee on other needful occasions. The Rev. W.
N. Molesworth generously undertook to use what influence he had with
Members of Parliament, on their behalf. During this time there was
much written correspondence going on between those conducting the Bill
through Parliament and the committee.
Mr. Edward Hooson, of Manchester, moved—
"That this Co-operative Conference
presents its grateful acknowledgments to John Bright, Esq., M.P., for the
valuable advice he tendered to the promoters of the 'Bill for the
Amendment of the Industrial Provident Societies Acts;' for the great
service of his personal assistance at every stage of the Bill; for
arranging the interviews of the deputation with the Board of Trade, and
for his indispensable offices in soliciting Mr. J. S. Estcourt to take
charge of the Bill in the House of Commons—services not to be lightly
estimated or the less scrupulously and respectfully acknowledged because
they are such as the working class, bent upon self-improvement, can ever
command from Mr. Bright."
Mr. Bright's subsequent acknowledgment of the vote was in the
following terms, in a letter addressed to Mr. William Cooper, Oldham Road,
Rochdale:—
"Rochdale, January 19, 1863.
"Dear Sir,—I have to thank you and the Conference of Delegates for their
resolution. It sets forth far greater services than I was able, but
not more than I was wishful, to render you. I hope the Bill will do
much good, which will be a satisfaction to all those who supported it."
Mr. Greenwood, the chairman, moved—
"That this Conference convey to the Rt.
Hon. Sotheron Estcourt, M.P., the respectful thanks of all friends of
Co-operation for the courtesy and liberality with which he undertook the
charge of their 'Bill for the Amendment of the Industrial Societies Acts;'
giving to it the advantages of his parliamentary position, which ensured
it successfully passing the ordeal of the House of Commons."
Mr. Estcourt, who was then in Italy, replied in a letter to Mr. Abram
Greenwood as follows:—
"Florence, 16th February, 1863.
"Sir,—I have just received the complimentary resolution
passed at the delegates' meeting of the Co-operative Societies, held at
Oldham on the 25th of December, in acknowledgment of the part which I took
last session in regard to the 'Bill for the Amendment of the Industrial
Societies Acts.'
"I request you to convey to the delegates the satisfaction
which I feel in receiving this mark of their approval; and to assure them
that it was a pleasure to me to undertake the work.
"I cannot forbear reminding you that in the preparation of
the Bill and in carrying it through the House of Commons I received great
assistance from the President of the Board of Trade and the Solicitor
General; that the able lawyer employed by the Government in preparing
their measures, was allowed to revise my scheme; and that Lord Portman
took charge of the Bill in the House of Lords and greatly conduced to its
success by his judicious management. I am, air, your obedient
servant,
"J. SOTHERON ESTCOURT."
Mr. Charles Howarth, the earliest organising co-operator of Rochdale,
moved—
"That the chairman of this Conference be
instructed to convey to Lord Portman, on the part of the co-operative
representatives present, their sincere acknowledgments of the great
service he has rendered to the industrial interests of the English workman
by his kindness in undertaking the labour and responsibility of conducting
the 'Bill for the Amendment of the Industrial Societies Acts' through the
House of Lords, and to assure his lordship that the co-operators of
England will know how to appreciate the consideration shown to the rights
of labour by the passing of this measure."
Lord Portman's answer was made in the following terms to Mr.
Cooper:—
"Bryanston, Blandford, Jan. 24, 1863.
"Sir,—I have the greatest confidence in the Co-operative
industrial and friendly societies, and have laboured to aid them ever
since I have been in Parliament, now 40 years; so I am not likely to fail
in my exertions while I have strength to be useful. Your obedient
servant,
PORTMAN."
Mr. Councillor Smithies, of Rochdale, moved—
"That this Conference would ill discharge its duty if it
separated without expressing its high sense of the obligations the
co-operators of England are under to Edward Vansittart Neale, Esq., for
the munificent interest which he has ever taken in their welfare.
Especially this Conference desires to record its heartiest thanks for his
legal and professional services in drawing up this 'Bill for the Amendment
of the Industrial Societies Acts'—services rendered with promptness and
without stint; for advice, assistance, and influence, watchfully and unintermittently given through every stage of the Bill, for which the
members of every co-operative society in the kingdom owe Mr. Neale
personal thanks."
Mr. Neale's answer was of a nature to add to the obligations
cooperators were under to him. It was expressed in the following letter:
"West Wickham.
"Dear Sir,—I trust that the Bill which I have been
instrumental in obtaining for you will inaugurate an era of genuine
co-operative effort among the working men of England, whence I am certain
that an incalculable amount of good of every sort will arise. But we
must be patient and persevering. The great thing to impress upon the
minds of the workers is the importance of seeking to raise the position of
their class, instead of limiting their efforts to raising their own
position as individuals. This lies at the bottom of the dispute
about giving workers, as such, a share in profits. A man who has
saved up a little capital may say, 'I shall get more if I take all the
profits to myself.' But will his children get more? Is it
not far more important to him, as a working man, to bring about a state of
things whereby his children, or other relatives, will share in the profits
of capital, whatever their occupation may be, rather than to get a few
more shillings or pounds a year himself; while he leaves the present
state of things unchanged for every person connected with him who has not
saved up capital, or has not been fortunate enough to place it
advantageously? Very sincerely yours,
"E. V. NEALE."
Mr. James Dyson, of the Working Tailors' Association, moved
the following resolution, which was seconded by Mr. Edwards, of
Manchester, and carried:—
"That this Conference, composed of the
representatives of Co-operative Societies, desires to express its profound
sympathy with the family of the late Hon. Robert A. Slaney, M.P., in their
bereavement; and further desires to convey to them its high sense of, and
cordial thanks for his many and valuable labours in the Commons House of
Parliament to promote the passing of laws which have given permanence and
security to these societies, thus enabling the people of Great Britain to
organise for the improvement of their moral, social, physical, and
pecuniary condition, and for which the industrial classes will ever hold
his memory in grateful and sacred remembrance."
This resolution was replied to by Captain Kenyon Slaney,
son-in-law of the late member for Shrewsbury.
"Walford Hall, Shrewsbury.
"I have the honour to acknowledge the receipt of your letter of the
13th January, enclosing a copy of a resolution passed at a conference of
delegates from co-operative industrial societies, held at Oldham, on 25th
December, expressing in most kindly terms their warm appreciation of the
services rendered to their societies by the late Mr. Slaney, M.P. for
Shrewsbury, and tendering their sympathy and condolence to his family
under their bereavement.
"Such a record of Mr. Slaney's services, and of the
estimation in which such services were held, is most gratifying to those
to whom your communication is addressed. They know full well the
importance Mr. Slaney ever attached to co-operative societies, and the
zeal with which he applied himself, in Parliament and out of Parliament,
to promote the success of such institutions, and in all ways to advance
the interests and improve the condition of the industrial classes.
But it is rarely that such deeds obtain a grateful recognition like that
which it is now my duty to acknowledge. I am desired to convey to
the delegates of the co-operative societies, whom you so ably represent,
the warm and hearty thanks of every member of Mr. Slaney's family, for the
good feeling which has prompted the resolution; for the generous tribute
of gratitude and regard which has thereby been offered to his memory; and
for the sympathy so kindly expressed for those who mourn his loss."
In passing these resolutions of thanks, the co-operative
delegates spent gratefully and honourably their Christmas Day, 1863.
The North of England Wholesale Agency mentioned in another chapter was
founded the same day at the same meeting.
Oldham at that time was not the most encouraging place in the
world to visit on a Christmas Day, and it would be late in the evening
before many of the delegates would return by rail home. When all
England, that can get it, devotes itself to roast turkey, festivity, and
plum pudding, it is to the credit of these co-operators that they should
have given the whole day to railway journeys and prosaic delegate
business. Rochdale would be sure to do its share of this work, as
anyone can testify who has had personal intercourse with the Pioneers.
There has been on their part a consciousness of working for society as
well as for Rochdale—they desired to show what could be done—that others
might be incited to do the same. They cared for others, and this is
why so many care for them. They wished to raise the class to which
they belonged. They saw that the elevation of the working men as a
class was the best security for the individual advancement of its members,
and it is this sentiment, more than any success, which has given to
Rochdale Co-operators an honoured name.
The leading co-operators of the Society took the trouble to
get the resolutions of thanks recited, as well expressed as they could.
I suppose they knew that most persons carry a stock of hate on hand, and
that censure is always ready made. But praise is a very different
thing. It only proceeds from generosity or gratitude, and those are
deliberate sentiments. A man may rage without art, but he cannot
applaud sensibly without it. This is why the quality of a man's mind
is more easily seen in his praise than in his censure. Defamation
shows his feeling, praise his understanding; and if he wishes to give an
idea of his strong sense of a service rendered him, he can best do it by
showing that he accurately estimates it, and this is the only praise
anyone not vain, cares to receive, or which is an actual tribute to him.
The Pioneers put themselves to some cost to get their resolutions into
terms which they liked. They paid me 10s. to draft resolutions which
should include the individual services and characteristics of each person,
so that each vote should be different, and founded on personal knowledge.
Sixteen years ago, the Pioneers made a graceful
acknowledgment to the present Vicar of Spotland (who was then incumbent of
that church), for kindly services to them, and which services, it may now
be said, have increased with the years which have since elapsed. One
day they carried to Mr. Molesworth a beautiful bound copy of the "English
Hexapla," which bore the following inscription:—
"Presented to the Rev. W. N. Molesworth (incumbent of
Spotland), by the Educational Committee of the Rochdale Equitable
Pioneers' Co-operative Society, as a testimonial in recognition of his
valuable and disinterested services on behalf of the above Society and of
Co-operation generally.
"December 20th, 1861.
SAMUEL NEWTON, Secretary."
The Rev. Mr. Molesworth took a personal interest in the
Society almost from the commencement, and visited Mr. William Cooper, and
talked to him about it. It occurred to Mr. Molesworth that he would
like to be a member of it in order that he might watch its progress more
closely; but he could not overlook that if he joined it, and anything went
wrong with it, he would, perhaps, be regarded as morally responsible in
respect to it. A person of position belonging to a society, although
he had no connection with its management, would be thought to lend a sort
of guarantee of its financial and legal soundness, although all he might
have in his mind would be to assist a useful society calculated to promote
the social improvement of working people. Besides, if a society had
no legal recognition or limited liability, a person of means might be made
responsible in case of losses, for which members without means could not
practically be made liable. More from regard to others than himself,
it is within my knowledge that Mr. Molesworth asked Mr. Cooper "whether
the liability was limited." Mr. Cooper said "it was," but he
subsequently found he was mistaken. Mr. Molesworth then
considerately pointed out to him what an objectionable thing it was that
the members of the Society should each of them be liable to the full
extent of his means if anything went wrong. Mr. Cooper becoming
aware of the seriousness of this state of affairs, asked Mr. Molesworth,
and one or two others of the leading men of the Society, to meet at his
office and consider the matter. Mr. Molesworth complied with the
request, and brought with him several suggestions, which were adopted by
the meeting nearly, if not entirely, in the form in which he submitted
them. They were sent to Mr. Vansittart Neale, who returned them and
recommended them for adoption, and in that shape they were soon after
published.
-XVI-
QUERULOUS OUTSIDERS.
IT is no mean part of the art of progress to know
how to treat outsiders—that is supposing you have a good cause, clear
principles, and earnest advocates. Therefore let us look with
curiosity and intelligence on outsiders. If conversion is reasonably
treated, they will be insiders one day. Here I deal with querulous
outsiders—the discontented who are not ignorant—the critics who mean
mischief, and know it. They swarmed about the Rochdale Society for
years. Sometimes the shopkeeper is made an angry adversary by being
needlessly alarmed. A co-operative speaker will say, "Look at the
great profits made at the chief stores—£20,000, £30,000, or £40,000 a
year. All this is rescued from the shopkeepers." Nothing of
the kind. It is by buying wholesale by combination of capital; it is
by purchasers buying largely at the stores by combination; it is by
economy in distribution; it is by fewer shops, fewer servants, by avoiding
advertisements and costly display, that the chief profits are made.
The co-operator gains by avoiding the multiplied shops, the high rents,
the heavy taxes, the useless servants, the cost of advertisements, glarish
lights, and loss on unsold goods and bad debts. The co-operator
grows rich by picking up what the shopkeeper drops, before he touches the
tradesman's actual profits.
Co-operators are merely miners in the gold fields of
commerce, who find what the shopkeeper has overlooked. Many a
shopkeeper is made to grieve by the idea of the loss of profits he never
had and never would have had, had co-operators never been born. The
co-operator mainly gains by a superior mode of business and the natural
economy of concert.
The Rochdale Co-operators publish an almanack which may be
taken as their annual manifesto. It records their progress and
current opinions. It is compiled by various hands, and now and then
an article appears on the sheet which shows that the new writer is a
recent convert who fails to comprehend the traditions of this great
Society. In an almanack now and then there has been an attack on
shopkeepers, which a sagacious co-operator avoids. For instance, in
the year 1860 almanack there was a denial of the initiative principle
which makes co-operation a wholesome power. Here is the questionable
passage:—
"The present co-operative movement does not seek to level
the various social inequalities which exists in society as regards wealth,
excepting so far as enabling the labouring man to subscribe a portion of
the capital necessary: first, for the purchase of articles of consumption
from those, or as near to those as possible, who produce them, so as to
appropriate to himself the profits which now flow into the pockets of the
retail dealers; and next by enabling him also to assist in the
contribution of such capital as is necessary for the carrying on of his
own industrial occupation: by this means giving him a chance of
participating in the profits of his own labour, and removing it farther
out of the reach of men with a little capital to realise princely fortunes
out of the energy and industry of the people, while the people themselves
are barely, at the best, fed and clothed for the time. In a word,
the present co-operative movement does not seek to enforce, or carry out,
any particular doctrines of any particular individual. This
acknowledgment, on the part of the co-operators of the present day, ought
to set at rest the hitherto generally believed assertion that co-operation
is only the Utopian idea of such enthusiasts as St. Simon, Robert Owen,
Louis Blanc, and others, and that it is on that account impracticable."
Here is a needless tribute to public incompetence. This
disavowal of all the antecedents of co-operation might have answered some
purpose in the struggling days of the movement. In the day of its
triumph it was gratuitous. Had it not been for St. Simon, Robert Owen, and
Louis Blanc, and others, co-operation might not have
lifted up its head for centuries. Save for the genius of St. Simon, the
princely sacrifices of Owen, the brave risks of its eloquent advocates,
like Louis Blanc, hundreds of thousands of workmen who have now
competence, would have died the death of a blind proletaire, grateful for
the permission to toil, breed, suffer, and perish. [46]
This language was calculated to give the querulous outsider
good heart, who would renew his attempt to damage an adversary who was
defaming himself. There were, however, it must be owned, some few
cantankerous shopkeepers in Rochdale in the early days of the Store.
One instance, long forgotten, belonging to the pre-store days, deserves to
be told. When the flannel weavers were out on strike in 1844, they
were no doubt bad customers to the shopkeepers. It is very likely
the shopkeepers had no reason to admire them. No doubt their
necessities developed in them a strong desire for credit, attended by
feeble capacity of payment, and when the men added to their sills of
impecuniosity, the actual solicitation of assistance to sustain them on
strike, a shopkeeper in Yorkshire Street, in the town, of the outlandish
name of Pozzi, startled the weavers. He, like Mrs. Caudle, gave them
"a bit of his mind." He told them they were "vagabonds, and should
go to work." They were poor, but not idle men. They were
starving, but they were starving on principle. They had a spirit
above vagabondage, and they determined, as they said, "to punish the
shopkeepers who insulted them." Thus resentment, as well as social
philosophy, had to do in promoting the Store. This was thoroughly
English. Seldom does a reform in this country originate because it
is reasonable. It is an outrage or an insult which generally sets
the reforming conviction in a blaze. Many an early co-operative
weaver, who found difficulties causing the fire of principle to grow low
within him, was blown into flame again by the resentful recollection of
"that Pozzi." After seventeen years, as the Store Almanack of 1860
shows, his enraging memory was fresh in the co-operative mind.
Naturally the weavers on strike were under the impression that, as their
wages were principally spent at the shops, it was the interest of the
shopkeepers to aid them in increasing their wages. They, however,
obtained but "slender assistance." Many shopkeepers had no means of
aiding largely, and more had no sympathy with them, and not a few were
poor themselves by reason of the credit given by them to the weavers.
But if co-operators and trade unionists can be inconsiderate,
shopkeepers can be fools when they give their minds to it, and many
Rochdale tradesmen have shown desire and ability to distinguish themselves
in this way. In 1859, two years after the issue of the first part of
this history, and when they well know that co-operation—like John Brown's
soul—"was marching on," they took the field against Richard Cobden because
he was known to be friendly to co-operative workmen. At a subsequent
election, the shopkeepers supported Mr. Baliol Brett, a Tory lawyer, who
had never done anything and was unknown for any human service to the
people. The shopkeepers of Rochdale—not all of them, but a pretty
substantial crowd of them—sought to give the seat of Richard Cobden to an
adventuring Conservative barrister. So far as this was done not from
political coincidence of opinion, but with a view to trade interest, it
was not creditable.
To be without honest principle in commerce, is to be a
thief—that is what it is called in criminal courts. To be without
honest conviction and clear knowledge in public affairs and prefer your
private interest or ambition to the public good—that is to be a thief in
politics. Neither friendliness to co-operation nor opposition to it
is a reason for voting for any candidate. His general fitness to
serve the country is the only ground for preferring a member, as nations
go in their daily and ordinary march.
In 1859, the shopkeepers of Rochdale started a Tory gentleman
named Ramsay as the Anti-Store Candidate. He was selected on the
respectable principle of local politics, namely, that he had never done
anything. He was the author of no public reform; he had never
laboured for any popular and unfriended interest, and therefore was to be
electorally distinguished for his inability. This is the way the
tradesmen put him forward. I quote from one of their bills, taken
from the walls and preserved for me. It runs thus:—
"LOOK OUT!
"The shopkeepers of Rochdale will do well to 'look before
they leap' in the approaching struggle. They will do well to ask
this important question, 'Who are the men who are thus busying themselves
in adopting means to secure the election of Richard Cobden?'
"Are the shopkeepers aware that the chief supporters of the
Bright-and-Cobdenite faction are also the leading members of the
Co-operative Stores?
"Is it not notorious that George Ashford (and family
connections), Jacob Bright, John Petrie, Pagan (and their family
connections), Livsey, Kemp and Kelsall (and their family connections), who
are in the Radical front ranks, are all part and parcel of these
Stores—are aiders and abetters of this iniquitous system?
"Will the shopkeepers of Rochdale never take a lesson from
the past? Will they never be aroused to the real state of their
affairs? Will they still go on aiding the men who are fostering the
system which is destined at no distant period to snatch their daily bread
from their very jaws?
"If the shopkeepers of Rochdale are fully aware of all these
facts will they, I ask, give the vital stab to their future prospects by
deliberately voting for the Bright-and-Cobden faction?
"There is but one sane course open to them, and that is to
vote for Ramsay, liberty, and justice! and not for Cobden and Livsey's pet
bastile!!
A SHOPKEEPER."
This precious bill bore no personal name, but the shopkeepers
did not disown it. It bore no printer's name, so that its parentage
could not readily be traced. The answer to it bore a pretty broad,
brief, abrupt and intelligible headline; it bore also a printer's address,
and was signed by several distinguished and honoured names. Here it
is. I have sent the printer one of the original placards to quote
from:—
"TORY LIES.
"A handbill, anonymous, and without
printer's name, has been industriously circulated among the shopkeepers of
this borough, seeking by absolute and positive falsehoods to prejudice
them against Richard Cobden.
"The statements referred to are to the effect that the
leading supporters of Richard Cobden are connected with the Rochdale
Cooperative Store.
"Without expressing any opinion concerning the 'Store,' we,
the undersigned, being all the persons named in the handbill, give the
most unqualified contradiction to the statement, and assert that we have
no connection with that establishment directly or indirectly.
"Sir Alexander Ramsay's cause must, indeed, be considered
hopeless by his friends when they are compelled to resort to such
disgraceful means in the vain attempt to secure their ends.
"Shopkeepers of Rochdale! don't be blinded to your true
interests by the silly attempts of the Tories to throw dust in your eyes.
No man has done more for the trade of the country generally, nor for the
shopkeepers especially, than has Richard Cobden. Give him your
votes, and show the Tories that tricks and falsehood will never succeed
with honest people.
"GEORGE ASHFORD.
"JOHN PETRIE.
"JACOB BRIGHT.
"JOHN PAGAN.
"KELSALL & KEMP.
"THOMAS LIVSEY. |
"Rochdale, April 18th, 1859."
The placard sent me while the contest raged bore these words:
"Richard Cobden will be member for Rochdale.—William Cooper." And so
it proved. Tradesmen have, however, small cause to complain if the
co-operator is sometimes antagonistic to them when they play these tricks.
This is a sufficient example of the cantankerous tradesman on the stump.
The chief figures which used to come into prominence in the
crowd of outsiders would be newspaper correspondents and pamphleteers
under the name of "Merchant," "Looker on," or, of course, "Working man,"
who was a favourite character in which the outsiders appeared. There
was some sense in the objections which the shop keeper put under these
disguises. The stores were inefficient, and these objectors did much
to improve them. In cases in which I wrote pamphlets in reply, [47]
I urged upon co-operators that the thing wanted in most districts is a
good central, well-supplied depot, on the co-operative plan, which can
engage and maintain a good buyer-in. [48] The
goods would then be carefully selected, the profits would be higher, and
the smallest store would thus be on a level with the greatest wholesale
shopkeeper. But it takes time to educate co-operative societies to
see their own interests. Many prefer blundering along, making bad
purchases for the sake of some immediate gain, while they lose in
character, and injure themselves, the members, and the cause in the long
run. This short-sightedness will cure itself in time. It can
be cured by patience and reason. It cannot be cured by reproaches.
Every society, of course, has a right to buy where it pleases. We
must wait till good sense and enlightened interest gain the day. Men
like our incendiary "Working Men" appear in every place; but they get
fewer and fewer as the great principle travels on. There are errors
and failures everywhere, but they are eclipsed by successes so unexpected
and so important, that the great Social Reform advances, and co-operation
is the now accepted principle of self-help for the people.
Every society has its "Working Men" objectors. They
appear in every town, occasionally of a very bad type. They crawl
out of the slime of competition. Sometimes they mean well, and some
times they don't. I have seen them before, and know what they intend
to say before they speak, and it would not be difficult to answer them in
the dark. In the early years of a cause it is useful to notice them,
and they like it. If they write like candid men, respect them; if
they do not, answer them within certain limits. Error,
misrepresentation, misapprehension, and prejudice are serpents, alive at
both ends. If you cut them in two, they still live; while they can
wriggle, they may sting. Since, however, they are damaged when
divided, it is good policy to chop at them.
-XVII-
FOUR DANGEROUS YEARS.
WHEN the slave war, or rather the war instigated by
the Southern American party in defence of slavery, came, it was known that
the Cotton Famine would follow: the mills of Lancashire and Yorkshire
would stop, hundreds of thousands of families would be without work—and
that meant being without food—John Bull would be short of calico, and
manufacturers short of profits. Then it was predicted that
co-operation would stop spinning like a top, when the momentum of
working-class prosperity was withdrawn.
The political economists shook their heavy heads in their
wise way. Not the better sort, like Mr. J. S. Mill or Professor
Fawcett, who often vindicated co-operation. The professor, however,
sent out in "Macmillan," a small professional moan—chiefly of kindly
warning, but still distrustful of the new forces of concerted industry—to
stand the shock of the dangerous years coming. He said:—
"Will a body of workmen, combined in a
cotton' manufactory, be able to keep together during two or three years,
at low profits, and withstand the difficulties of a financial crisis?
This is a problem which remains to be solved" [49]
When the dangerous years (from 1861 to 1864) set in, we had
Times correspondents writing from Rochdale. What they had to
tell will be remarkable reading for many years to come. In 1862 the
relief committees had not dispensed very much among the unemployed
families. On December 19th of that year, the Times
commissioner wrote from Rochdale, saying:—"It is never very easy to
ascertain with any degree of accuracy the extent to which the unemployed
have taxed their own resources to meet the calamity which has fallen upon
them. The investments most preferred by the working classes vary in
different towns. In some the savings bank is the favoured
depository; in others, building and benefit societies are the fashion; and
of late there has been a very general run on the co-operative
associations. On this account, comparison of savings bank accounts
will not always be a correct indication of what is going on. In
several towns where I have inquired into the point I have found that the
withdrawals in this year of distress very little exceed those of last
year, and the explanation given was that the operators had just begun to
withdraw their deposits in order to invest them in this new movement.
In Rochdale it may be said that the co-operative societies, which are on a
very large scale, have absorbed pretty nearly the whole of the savings of
the working classes. There are here three great concerns managed on
this principle—the Store, the Corn Mill, and the Cotton Mill, representing
among them a capital of close upon £140,000."
The "problem" was getting itself "solved" pretty well, and
cooperative societies had no small share in enabling the people of the two
great cotton spinning counties to resist the recognition of a slave
dominion. But our commissioner relates unexpected facts of the
Rochdale Store:—
"Last quarter," he said, "the profit to members on
purchases amounted to 2s. 5d. in every pound—in other words, for every
17s. 7d. spent the member got a pound's worth of goods; so that instead of
being perpetually in debt, as in the old times, the working man who deals
here is absolutely earning for himself the profit which went into the
shopkeeper's pocket, [50] and probably gets a better
article into the bargain. The more comfortably he
lives, the larger is his share of the profits at the end of the year.
One account taken at hazard, among others which I saw myself in the books
of the Store, sets the advantages of the system to the working man in a
very clear light. It was that of a member who in September, 1854,
had £7 10s. standing to his credit. For all the eight years he had
gone on clothing and feeding his family at the Store, he had never paid in
a farthing in any way to increase his account; on the contrary, he had
drawn out at various times £90 odd, and yet at the end of last quarter he
had £50 placed against his name. The profits on his purchases during
the last eight years, with interest, had actually produced him £132 10s.,
or rather more than £16 a year. In all probability, if he had gone
on dealing all this time at an ordinary shop he might have spent 10 per
cent. more, and would have been in debt at the end of the time some £5 at
the least. It is only natural that the numbers of the members and
the business done should have increased rapidly, and that the working
classes in different parts of the country should have endeavoured to copy
the very successful model thus set up. The capital increased so
fast, in fact, spite of all the extensions, that it outgrew the
necessities of the Society, and it became necessary to find other
employment for it. First a Corn Mill was established, which has now
been at work nine years, and in 1861 made a profit of £10,000. The
original capital invested here was £2,000, and it has now risen to nearly
£30,000, of which £9,000 has been contributed by the Store. It does
a large trade in the surrounding district, and, like the Equitable
Pioneers' Store, supplies other stores round about with goods wholesale.
From this the co-operators took a still higher flight, and entered on an
experiment which at first sight seemed not a little hazardous. They
conceived the idea of combining labour and capital, of being their own
employers, and sharing among themselves the fruits of their own labour."
No more impressive account of the practical economy of
co-operation has ever been given. The good sense of concerted action pays
when it yields £16 a year profit to a working man's family. It is worth
listening to a writer whose words have gone all over the world. He says
further:—"The Co-operative Manufacturing Society, which was formed in
1857, owns now one of the finest mills in the town, fitted with first-rate
machinery, and another of equal dimensions, I am told, is in course of
erection. Its capital is now £68,000, and in 1861, it divided
profits to the amount of £5,599. It appears to have been skilfully
managed from the first, and,
though it suffers in common with other concerns, it is still able to run
three days a week. I wish to point out how materially the existence here
of the co-operative societies must have alleviated the pressure of the
distress. In its early stages the movement had to encounter no little
opposition from those who scented Communism, Socialism, and all sorts of
bugbears in it; but its improving effects on the character and condition
of the working classes are so unmistakable that none but the most selfish
could refuse it their support. Manufacturers, as a rule, prefer
co-operatives as workmen; the habits of self-reliance, prudence, and
order which their connection with these societies engenders raise them
considerably over the ordinary class, and their economy has certainly put
them in a better position to bear the strain of the times."
Thus the "problem" of the political economist got "solved." Co-operation
proved to be no hothouse plant, requiring hot-air apparatus and infinite
watching, forcing, and coddling; but a hale, hearty, winter shrub, which
will take root in any good soil, enjoys a blast, and grows strong by
exposure.
The statements in the Times were written by a man of ability in
putting facts, and not without sympathy with self-helping sense among
working people. The profit to a family of well-managed, well-sustained
co-operation, was never packed into smaller compass, or brought before the
public eye in a more palpable way, than in the sentence in which he says
"that a single family saved as much as £16 a year for eight years, while
had they continued buying at the ordinary shops, they would have paid 10
per cent. more for their goods, and have been at least £5 in debt." Here
is a distinct, solid, complete, picturesque thing said. This is one of
those portable statements which the most casual reader can carry away in
his mind. Art in statement is like cultivated taste in exhibiting
treasures; the picture or statuette must be seen with the glory of space
around it. All crowding is detraction. Multiplicity is not magnificence,
as the uneducated think. All details have their place in statement, and
out of place they are like meaner things which crowd about the nobler,
hide the proportions of beauty, and distract, torment, and outrage the
trained eye. The commissioner of the Times notices that communicativeness
of the Rochdale Pioneers which has made theirs the great propagandist
Store. He remarks—"Few are so communicative as to their actual position
as the Equitable Pioneers, who are too firmly established to fear even
this severe strain; but the restricted trade and diminished working
capital must have told
on the greater number. The trade of the Rochdale Store in the twelvemonth
has fallen off by about one-third on the year, and
£21,000 has been withdrawn from the funds, of which, probably,
£16,000 at least has been withdrawn by unemployed members in
order to meet the distress. All of it has come back to the Store in
the purchase of provisions, and the profits on the purchasers of the
year, together with the payment of share subscriptions reduce the
actual loss of capital to little more than £1,000. There is no transfer of
stock, but the rule of the Society is that any member may withdraw as much
of his capital invested as he pleases down to £5,
and, with the special leave of the committee, down to £2. No deposits are
allowed below that amount, and those whose necessities
will not allow them to stop there must draw out the whole. About 300
members have been thus compelled to leave the Society, to rejoin it, it is
to be hoped, when better times comes round."
They all came back, and, as an Irishman would say, many more came back who
had never left. The above statement includes particulars of the rules and
practices of the Rochdale Store, which will be informing and welcome to
all readers. Narrative should, like leading articles in a newspaper,
resemble a Scotch house, and
be self-contained. The Times itself became the "leading journal" by this
art. When its columns were crowded for five days with reports of Palmer's
trial, the leading article upon it on the sixth day, when the case ended,
gave a complete account of the fat, horseracing, rascally, surgical poisoner's trial, which the busy man could
understand though he had never read a line of the reports. The article was
self-contained. It was lighted up with outside facts. The above-cited
passages introduce into this story details which make it complete in
itself, without irrelevant and formal repetition. It is of no use
listening to a speaker, or reading an author, if you require first to hear
or read someone else to understand him.
But the immediate point before the reader is to understand how Rochdale
stood the slave and cotton storm. Co-operation stood like the Eddystone
Lighthouse—as immovable as the north pole.
In December, 1861, when the cotton panic had commenced, the cash received
at the Store over their counters for the sale of provisions and other
articles of household and personal use amounted to £176,000. During the
year of 1865, the cash received reached £196,000, showing an increase of
£20,000. Their capital in 1861 was £42,000; in 1865 it was £78,000. Four
years before their members were 3,900; four years later they were 5,300,
showing an in
crease during the panic of 1,400 members. This looks as though co-operative
crafts were places of safety in a storm.
In 1862 these Pioneers built a new shop at Blue Pits. There's a
name!—an honest name, however, for the pits deserve it. This
Blue Pit shop cost £700. Next year they built a slaughter-house and
stables, at a cost of £1,000; and also a new shop at Pinfold,
which cost £1,000. This was pretty well for 1863. In 1864 they put up a
Store at Spotland-Bridge, at a cost of £1,500; and another in the Oldham
Road, at a cost of £1,700; and in 1863 they finished the Buersil branch,
at a cost of £1,000. The Pioneers modestly said that these buildings do
not disgrace the neighbourhood in which
they stand. The fact is, there was little or nothing to disgrace—there
being no lively or inspiring buildings anywhere about—and these stores
are cheerful, wholesome, and not unpleasing buildings.
The Town Hall, Rochdale; which is a municipal glory now, was not then
erected.
Nor is this all. The Pioneers commenced excavations in Toad Lane (which
ought to be called the Pioneers' Highway, for it goes up a hill, and they
have made the hill of difficulty easy) for the purpose of erecting a great
Central Store, which they hoped would be an ornament to the town. There
was reason for this hope; for Rochdale needed and deserved some
architectural improvement. During the four years of "famine," the members
drew out £83,000;
the Society having been a savings bank on this great scale. Better than
this, the Pioneers gave £750 for the relief of the distressed and to other
charitable purposes. And quite as honourable to their intelligence as
these gifts are to their humanity, they had appropriated £1,840 to the purposes of self-education. This is enough to show
that the working men of Rochdale know how to dream dreams, and that the
weavers' co-operative dream turned out a substantial and instructive
reality.
If the reader has the courage to go through a paragraph having figures in
it (p. 142), he may see how the Rochdale Store fared in the eventful years
when the slave owners fought for the whip. The odd hundreds and fractions
of pounds, shillings, and pence, usually included in any financial
narrative, are omitted here. The writer recognises—what is not often
done—that the general reader is
not an auditor. He can only take figures in the bulk. The common rule is
to fill into any narrative containing figures all the minor amounts and
fractions, just as though the reader was going to send for the books and
go over them to test the exact truth of the statement, in which case the
writer would have to wait a fortnight before the reader would be able to
attend to the continuation of the argument.
In the following statement the reader will find the grand figures in one
round honest bulk, with all the fractional edges chipped off, so that they
will not scratch the memory nor irritate the understanding.
Returns from Rochdale show the position of co-operation in that town for
the four years preceding and subsequent to the civil war in America. From
1857 to 1860 the members increased from 1,800 to 4,600, the capital from
£15,000 to £57,500, the business from £80,000 to £174,000, the profits
from £5,000 yearly to £15,000.
From 1860 to 1864, the full period of the cotton crisis, the profits
increased in uneven gradations from £15,000 to £22,000. In 1861,
the Society felt the effects of the scarcity of cotton. In the March
quarter of that year the receipts for sales were £47,000; in the
December quarter they had fallen to £42,000. In 1862, the cotton
famine was the most severe. Two-thirds of the operatives of Rochdale were
almost entirely out of work. The greater part of the mills were entirely
closed, and the people had to subsist to a great
extent, on their previous savings. This year the number of members of the Store decreased 500. The capital of the Society decreased
£4,500. The cash received for sales decreased £32,000; yet this
year the profits made amounted to £17,000. Not only did co-operation stand
its ground during a period which it was supposed would destroy it, but the
Store, the Corn Mill, and Manufacturing Society of Rochdale gave together
£1,500 for the relief of the unemployed, and the Store alone made £70,000
profit for its members. The Corn Mill Society made £10,000 a year profit
in 1860 and 1861. In 1862, the profits fell to £8,000, but next year they
returned to £10,000 again. The Manufacturing Society of Rochdale kept up
its full payment of wages during the cotton famine, ran more time than any
mill in the neighbourhood, and subscribed £3 weekly to the Distress Fund.
These societies of working men took their place by the side of
manufacturers in the mill and market, and it does not appear that they
shrunk from any responsibility which gentlemen in times of public distress
undertake.
Productive manufactures fared no less hopefully as far as they went. We
are in the habit of saying productive manufactures, in order to
distinguish production from distribution. Of course all manufactures are
productive—either of dividends or deficits—and of course always create
articles of utility or desire. Manufacturing, however, had not then, nor
has yet, got into complete co-operative ways. The mills reputedly
co-operative of that date were mainly joint-stock enterprises with a dash
of co-operation in the prospectus. In 1862, manufacturing societies of
this nature in Rochdale worked three days a week, which was greatly above
average of the time worked by the mills of the town. In Rochdale and its
suburbs there were then 93 cotton mills, rather over three-fourths of
which wholly ceased working. Taking the average of the whole, they worked
less than one day per week. It was a creditable and unexpected thing that
a semi-co-operative manufacturing mill which, it was said, would first
fall in a cotton crisis, should find itself able to work more time than
any of its competitive competitors.
The question, during the distress from which the working people suffered,
was as to whether co-operators were to be entitled to relief. The Central
Executive Relief Committee, of which the Lord Derby of that day was
chairman, considered the question of disqualifying co-operators and other
persons from participating in the
national subscriptions then made. It was at this time that Lord Derby
presented a scheme for the equitable administration of that fund, which
was marked by a generous and unforeseen discrimination which has not been forgotten to this day. Lord Derby said:—
"The co-operative societies stand upon a peculiar footing. The societies
known by this name comprise provision and clothing stores and flour mills,
which are conducted to a great extent on co-operative principles; but
cotton manufactories, called co-operative, are generally, if not
universally, simply joint-stock companies of limited
liability, the capital of which has been subscribed in small shares,
chiefly by workmen in the cotton districts, and which are often built and
conducted with the aid of loans. They have arisen out of motives which do
the highest honour to the operative classes; and there is no question but
they have induced habits of frugality, temperance, and self-restraint,
which have operated greatly to the
benefit of the working classes morally and physically. But it is
indisputable that the shares in some of the co-operative societies are at
the present moment greatly depreciated, and, in some cases,
actually valueless. Is, then, the possession, say, of one or more shares
in one of these societies to exclude the holder from a title to
relief? On the principle applied to the savings banks, the answer should
be in the affirmative; and the more so, as the investment
hitherto has yielded a larger interest. But it is to be remembered, on the
other hand, that whatever has been invested in the savings banks realises,
on its withdrawal, the whole of its nominal amount; whereas the
co-operative shares are, in many cases, not only depreciated, but, if
compelled to be sold, would realise little or nothing
to the possessors. The utmost, therefore, which can fairly be required is,
that the holder shall have mortgaged his share, and that he is not at the
present moment deriving any pecuniary benefit from
it. In such a case, I think the holder might fairly be entitled to relief,
as having, for the time, no other resources."
Dr. Watts, at the meeting when this was read, pointed out that shares in
co-operative stores were not mortgageable; and mentioned instances of
great hardship where sums had to be withdrawn, at a loss, before relief
could be obtained.
Lord Derby, in reply, said: "I have not even stated that those conditions
should be insisted upon in all cases. The whole intention of the paragraph
is to moderate the application of the strict principle."
Lord Egerton, of Talton, quoted the previous statement of the committee,
that these were cases for forbearance, and that it would not be wise to
discourage habits of forethought, adding:—
"I can assure Dr. Watts that it is the general opinion of the Executive
Committee that these cases should meet with the greatest forbearance, and
be looked most carefully to, so that those who have profited by the
opportunity of laying by some small store for themselves may not, in these
days of adversity, be left entirely helpless."
The co-operators were not destined to find on local committees the same
sense of industrial justice as animated the committee inspired by Lord
Derby. In the face of these strong recommendations the local committee
turned a deaf ear to the appeals of co-operative shareholders. Hence there
arose the co-operative shareholders' Central Relief Committee, which in
its public address remarked:—
"The mere refusal of money is only a part of the injustice. Thus, the
girls of co-operative, shareholders have been refused admission into the
sewing classes. The articles of clothing so generously contributed have been refused to co-operators, though frequently in greater
need of them than others who obtained them. Many have their clothes in the
pawnshop, and yet at the release of goods therefrom, a few weeks ago, in
Haslingden, not an article was returned that belonged to co-operative
shareholders."
Lord Derby took a just and considerate view of the claims of co-operators; but the shopkeepers on the committees took a shabby revenge upon their
humble rivals. But that distressed them not. They got through with
cheerful hearts.
-XVIII-
HALTING ON THE WAY.
IN 1844, the Equitable Pioneers, after a long period
of controversy and distrust, founded their Store upon the principle of
taking purchasers into partnership. From that time is dated the
successful career of co-operative distribution, which before the adoption
of that principle was in most towns vacillating, uncertain, and often
ignominious in its operations. Many years later, when the value of
partnership in consumption had been triumphantly tested, it was resolved
to apply it to productive co-operation. In 1855, steps were taken to
erect a spinning mill, which commenced business with 96 looms. In
1855, there was fitted up a second mill with new machinery. The two
mills were calculated to run 50,000 spindles. The principle on which
this mill was founded was that of taking the labourer into partnership,
and giving him a reasonable share of the profits, which were the joint
produce of capital, and the industry, good-will, good skill, and the
carefulness of the workmen. It was strongly hoped that the sagacity
of the Rochdale men would successfully set manufactures on the same ground
of equity on which they had placed distribution. The determination
of the promoters of the new mills was to carry into workshops the same
social advantages they had created in homes. It was believed that
success in Rochdale in creating a permanent industrial partnership would
have great influence in other towns. Even on the Continent the
success of the experiment was inquired after with great interest. It
was known as a rule that workmen made bad masters. The subjection in
which they have been kept, the dependence in which they have lived, the
beggarly income which, as a rule, comes to them (the lowest for which
poverty and competition compel them to sell their unwilling services), the
parsimony of life imposed upon them—enter into their souls and narrow
their judgment of their fellows. When they become masters themselves
they are often jealous of the success of their late comrades. They
regard good wages for good services, which make them profit, as so much
money taken out of their own pockets. They aim at getting the utmost
work out of those they employ, just as the worst master under which they
have served did unto them. What they wished to be done to them when
they were workmen, they commonly forget to do to others when they become
employers themselves. Their masters kept all the profits in their
own hands, and they determined to do the same thing. Therefore,
friends of industrial progress were very anxious about the success of the
co-operative mill, and great admiration was expressed of the Rochdale
workmen that established it, when they showed the fine spirit of founding
a real industrial partnership.
This excellent and long-looked-for vision of equity and
industry loomed hopefully for a time in the immediate distance, and then
went out of sight again. The "share list" being open to the whole
town, shares were taken up by numerous persons who knew nothing of
cooperation, and by others who cared little for it, and by many who
actively disliked it; and the rule giving a participation of profit to
workmen was rescinded.
The two noble engines erected in the mill of 60-horse power,
one named "Co-operation," and the other "Perseverance," [51]
had to be rechristened by the more revelant names of "Joint-stock," and "
Greed." As soon as the facts became noised abroad, the advocates of
the artisan ceased to look to Rochdale for that organisation of industry
which should terminate the increasing and unprofitable war between capital
and labour. Thus co-operation halted on the way.
An article upon Co-operative Societies in the London
Spectator (April 16, 1864), made this assertion:—"At Rochdale, the
system of admitting journeymen to participation in profits was abandoned
after trial."
"Abandoned after trial," suggests that it had been tried and
did not answer. The truth is, it was frustrated during successful
trial; it was not abandoned, it was put to death.
Professor Newman observed in a communication to the present
writer (Jan. 23, 1863):—
"Co-operative manufacturing 'hangs fire'
in the matter that the members' interest as capitalists overpowers their
sympathy with hirelings. If it be true that, as capitalists, they
gain nothing by interesting the hireling in the prosperity of the concern,
this means that co-operative capital can compete with private capital on
equal terms; then the problem is really simplified. Each man who
saves at all may be capitalist somewhere, though he be merely hireling
elsewhere; and, by co-operative stores, and abstinence from strong drink,
all who have health and youth can save. But if co-operative capital
cannot—or where it cannot—compete on equal terms with private capital,
it becomes the interest of the co-operative capitalists to take the
hirelings into quasi-partnership, by some bonus or other on the general
success. But, by one or both methods, I think the way is open for
prudent persons whenever moderate prosperity is general. But until
the townsmen understand that the cause of the peasants is their own cause,
and that depression of the country people weighs down the artisans, I do
not expect any general and considerable elevation."
Professor Newman, though an author upon Political Economy,
distinctly recognises the interest which workmen have when they become
capitalists, of taking those in their employ into partnership with them.
At that time, it was believed that the partnership system had been tried
in Rochdale, and that the co-operators themselves had relinquished it.
Whereas, they never did so; they never mistrusted the principle—they
never gave it up; it was forced from their hands in the fourth year of its
trial. The co-operators, like the Swedish monarch Charles, "were
overmatched, overpowered, and outnumbered." The discredit was not
upon the co-operators of that day. We shall describe the class of
persons by whom the evil was accomplished.
The Almanac of 1860 said:—"The object of the Rochdale
Co-operative Manufacturing Society is to provide arrangements by which
its members may have the profits arising from the employment of their own
capital and labour in the manufacturing of cotton and woollen fabrics, and
so improve their social and domestic condition. The profits which
arise from the business of the Society (first paying interest on capital
after the rate of £5 per cent. per annum) are divided amongst the
members, giving an equal percentage to capital [52]
subscribed and labour performed. Each member has the same amount
of votes and influence, whatever the amount of his investments." In
1861 the editor of the Almanac again repeated the same clear, sensible,
semi-equitable and hopeful announcement.
In 1864 the co-operators hung their harps upon the willows of
Mitchell Hey, and sang no more. At the same time they gave one
good-natured but instructive and disowning shriek in the Almanac.
They said:—"The principal object of the founders of this Society was the
equitable division of the profits arising from the manufacturing of cotton
and woollen fabrics. They believed that all who contributed to
the realisation of wealth, ought to participate in its distribution.
To this principle the Society has proved recreant, to the great regret of
its originators."
When, therefore, the anti-co-operators in Rochdale took the
rule by the throat which gave only a share of profit to workmen, and
strangled it, the gold-tinted eye of capitalism elsewhere grew bright on
hearing of this proceeding, and there was rejoicing in countless
counting-houses of manufactories where men had for generations worked like
horses and died like dogs.
Early in 1860, the enemy began to appear in the field, and a
great meeting was held in September in the Public Hall, Baillie Street, to
discuss the question of "bounty or no bounty to labour." No
doubt those hideous words "bonus and bounty" were the beginning of the
mischief, and made the ignorant shareholders believe they were actually
giving away their money in some foolish manner. Whereas, the profits
divided on labour represent the profits created by labour, over and above
that which, in the long run, would exist, if the participation is
withheld. An unregarded workman gives more than merely dull, sullen,
careless, uninterested service, during which he conspires—by trade unions
or otherwise—to extort from his employer all he can, because he believes
his employer conspires to withhold from him all he is able. This
sort of industry is merely silent spite. At the great meeting, all
the orators of greed appeared to argue that the workman was paid the
market value of his labour, and that was the fair end of him. This
sort of argument was for many years in great force in the distributive
stores. It was argued that the purchaser obtained in goods the
market value of his money, and what more did he want? Nearly two
generations of men lived and lied and died, among whom this question was
argued, before they could be taught to see that, by giving customers an
interest in coming to the Store, these customers would themselves, by the
certainty and magnitude of their purchases, create the very profits which
were to be shared among them. It will probably take as long before
it will be believed that the labourer in a manufactory can equally
contribute the profits accorded to him. The conditions of production
are more complicated than those of distribution, and it will take time and
patience to discover all the methods whereby every person engaged in a
manufactory shall be induced to do his best in consideration of his being
a partner in the profits. At the great meeting of 1860, the old
Pioneers stood up stoutly for the maintenance of the principle which
recognised the workman as a partner. One of them said: "It was the
duty of the Pioneers to base a manufactory on the same principle as a
Pioneers' Store. It was their duty, as the pioneers of the country,
to see that labour had its due." This was the public and generous
propagandist principle upon which the question was argued by the
co-operators at the first great meeting. When the votes were taken,
571 were given against the partnership of industry, and 270 for it.
Nevertheless, the motion was lost, as the rules require a majority of
three-fourths for the alteration of any law. Two years later, the
enemy having consolidated their forces, gave battle again, won the day,
and put back the dial of manufacturing industrial progress for their time,
so far as the example of Rochdale was concerned. As soon as this was
done, the cry went forth that the partnership of labour in Rochdale had
failed, and if anyone denied it, he was sharply asked the question, "If it
had not failed, why was the law of participation abrogated?" A rule
may be cancelled by cupidity, but it does not therefore follow that it has
failed. Greed of profit on the part of shareholders may have led to
procuring the abolition of a law which they thought injurious to them; and
who, having power to carry out their will, were not restrained by any
feeling of equity to others. It was freely said "the Society was
drifting to dissolution," as members were withdrawing their shares, and
placing them in other companies where no participation law was in force.
Several persons really did withdraw their shares, and others threatened to
do so. But no greater number of withdrawals took place than is
common in large societies, and this manufacturing company could well
afford to spare these retreating members; and it would have been more
honourable in them who did not agree with the law, to betake themselves to
some other society more congenial to their views, than remain in one they
had entered, for the purpose of abolishing the fundamental principle which
distinguished it. There was never ground for the assertion that the
Society was in danger of loosing its members or the needful supply of
capital by continuing the participation law. Many months previous to
the repeal of this law, the Society ceased taking new members, and, as a
consequence, declined taking additional money, except from those already
members, because members and money came in so rapidly that the Society did
not see how it could use profitably at the time all the capital it
possessed. It was well known that large numbers were ready to come
into the Society when the new list should again be opened. It is a
common experience of all societies that a certain class of shareholders
who want some special change made will threaten to withdraw from the
Society, and, of course, they spread the report that if they do that the
Society will break up. The importance of their remaining, and of
having their way, cannot in their opinion be too highly estimated.
Experience, however, shows that a society does not always fail because a
few persons think it will, or mean that it shall, or believe that it ought
to fail when they leave it. At that day various writers appeared to
defend the reactionary decision of the shareholders. One would sign
his letters under the mask of "Old Pioneer." This writer strongly
asserted that if the "anti-bountites," as they were called, had ceased to
be members, the Manufacturing Society could no longer go on. This
was quite an illusion; but it would have been fortunate for Rochdale if
they had withdrawn, and formed another society on the mere joint-stock
plan, which they had a right to do, and might have done without reproach.
Then they would have left the original Society to test itself and to stand
or fall on the principle on which it was founded. The charge against
the "anti-bountites" is, that when they found themselves strong enough to
seize this Society, which they had not founded, they did so, and prevented
an honest public experiment being tried, and brought discredit on
co-operation itself among those not acquainted with the facts of the case.
It was alleged that "co-operators of old standing" voted for the
destruction of the partnership of labour rule. If so they never
owned to it. But the main body of the old co-operators strove by
every means in their power, by their advocacy and their votes, to save it.
Mr. William Cooper, who was a member of the first Rochdale Equitable
Pioneer Society before and during the time the first rules were drawn up,
which was some months before the Toad Lane Store was opened for business,
knew all the persons who drew the black jointstock line across the
Manufacturing Society. He testified at the time that this defacement
was the act of the "newer members." When the disastrous night
arrived which was to cast conspicuous discredit on the partnership of
industry in Rochdale, 162 votes were given for the retention of the labour
profit rule, and 502 for its abolition.
When the white line of partnership of labour is for the first
time drawn across a manufactory, it is not a matter of rejoicing to see a
black line of the subjugation of labour supersede it.
Nothing can "pay" permanently, or ought to pay, which is not
conducted on a principle of fairness to all concerned in creating its
value. The pyramid of gain which is not based on equity is a mere
rascally pile, which an honest man would rather not touch.
On the recalcitrant night when the anti-co-operative
shareholders destroyed the hopeful law of industrial partnership, the
Co-operative Manufacturing Society numbered over 1,500, of whom only 664
were present. There was, therefore, half the members who either did
not attend the meeting, or who attended and did not vote, and who may be
classed as indifferent, neutral, or satisfied with the Society in its then
form. It is some satisfaction to record that only 502 out of 1,500
members actually lifted up their hands against the recognition of the
workman. If all the consequences to the credit of Rochdale which has
since followed upon that step had been foreseen, many of the 502 who
brought the discredit about, would, from mere pride of townsmanship, apart
from any care for the working class, have withheld their votes, and gone
elsewhere and founded another society. The chief movers against the
workers participating in the profits were at the time well-known to be of
the class of managers, overlookers, small tradesmen, and such like.
The mover of the motion to rescind the grand rule, and those who spoke on
the side of its abrogation, were drawn from these classes. The
committee of the Manufacturing Society were not all of them co-operators,
or they would have held as sacred the great law, and would have given all
their interest and influence against its repeal. But the majority of
the committee were themselves continually agitating against the principle
to the neglect of other important interests of the Society. One who
was within "The Ring," and who knew all about it, put me in possession of
the facts at the time. He admitted that some of the committee were
dashing, fast-going men—not the sort of men who usually cared for
principle. Their favourite argument against the labourer's claim of
sharing in the profits of his labour, was that of calling it a "Socialist
Theory."
Of course it was a " Socialist Theory." All
co-operative stores are founded on the same "Socialist Theory," which
gives profits to purchasers as well as to capitalists. Shopkeepers
of common-sense often act now upon the same "Socialist Theory," and give
their customers a share in the profits the customers help to create.
The "Socialist (manufacturing) Theory" is that the capitalist may be made
more secure, and even derive increased profits by making it the interest
of the labourer to co-operate with him in the production of gain.
In the great discussion which finally disestablished and
disendowed the workman as a sharer in the profits of his labour, James
Smithies made one of his best speeches on the occasion. Mr. Abraham
Greenwood and William Cooper were amongst the foremost champions of the
claim of the workmen. Mr. Holden also spoke on the same side.
I possess a full report of all the speeches published in the Rochdale
Spectator of the time, annotated with the names of all the speakers,
not given.
The under-placed tables show what this Society did down to 1866, when
profit was taken from the workers.
Year—July |
Funds |
Business |
Profits |
1854 |
... |
... |
... |
1855 |
... |
... |
... |
1856 |
... |
... |
... |
1857 |
4,351 |
12,081 |
888 |
1858 |
8,790 |
13,381 |
679 |
1859 |
26,613 |
16,483 |
1,770 |
1860 |
56,857 |
23,634 |
3,643 |
1861 |
69,347 |
47,229 |
5,237 |
1862 |
67,513 |
65,368 |
3,325 |
1863 |
82,850 |
86,437 |
3,688 |
This company still retains its old style of "Co-operative Manufacturing
Society"—fourteen years after it has relinquished the principle. In the
meantime, co-operation has got to re-establish the workman as a
participator in manufacturing profits. Masters may go back, as we have
seen at the Whitwood Collieries; but co-operators
should not. The trade unionists could carry the principle; and they will
do it when they get advisers who can think above the level of strikes. I
have seen Dutch workmen out in the Zuyder Zee accomplish what English
trade unionists have never had the courage
to attempt. As yet the main hope lies among unionists. In 1872 attempts
were made to re-establish co-operative manufacturing in Rochdale by
commencing card-making, but sufficient capital was not obtained to keep
the Society "on the cards."
In this place and elsewhere I prefer to use the phrase claim of the
workman instead of the term "right." A right of labour, like a right in
politics, is what can be got to be ruled, or conceded. A
claim is what ought morally to be conceded. A right is what is
conceded. But the claim holds good, and is to be persisted in. If workmen
were gentlemen in means no employed would dare to disallow it.
Comments on persons who, being directors or shareholders in a co-operative
company, and knowing it to be so, and joining it as co-operators, and then
turning upon the principle and betraying it or destroying it—do not apply
to persons who never were co-operators or accepted honour and trust as
such. They are of the joint-stock species—a different kind of commercial
creature altogether. But
co-operation means more and higher. It means the recognition of the
workmen, not indirectly—not in some infinitesimal, impalpable,
hypothetical, and abstract way—but directly, plainly, personally,
absolutely, permanently, as owner of an equitable share of the profits of
labour.
A co-operative society is one which shares its profits equitably with all
engaged in creating them, in labour and trade.
Mr. John Bright, meeting Mr. Abraham Greenwood, conversed on the subject
of the decision of the members of the Society, expressed his disapproval,
and asked if it could not be reversed, and the principle given another
trial. Mr. Greenwood expressed the opinion that it would be best to try
the principle again de novo, with members who have faith in that mode of
working, and that they
should be more careful as to who were admitted. Mr. Bright stated that a
large number of members of Parliament had taken great interest in the
experiment, and that he also knew manufacturers who would have been quite
willing to allow workmen to share in a certain amount of the profits if it
could have been carried out without themselves taking part in the
business, and if the workpeople would rely on the amounts stated to have
been realised, and
jealousy not allowed to interfere. Mr. Greenwood assured Mr. Bright that
good workmen believed in profit sharing, and that the principle had
attracted a superior class of employees to Mitchell Hey. Mr. Bright
replied that if the scheme had succeeded other manufacturers would have
been compelled to offer to employees some inducement for vigilance and
better work; that they ought not to be paid as a gift but for making the
capital of the employer more remunerative, the machinery do more work, and
to exercise greater economy in the material they had to manipulate. [53]
Mr. Bright's interest in this question is one of the most honourable
things in his career. Experience shows that once a social experiment which
has excited great hopes has been defeated, it is seldom that the same
generation try it again. It is a pity Mr.
Bright's advice was not acted upon. Mr. Bright never gave his
advice without giving his influence. Had an attempt been made to reverse
the decision against the principle on which the mill was founded, the
friendly minority would have been increased and probably inspired to
recommence their vital experiment.
Mr. John T. W. Mitchell, whose name the reader has seen (p. 54), was one
of the promoters and chairman—the Rochdale Congress Handbook records—of
this manufacturing society. As such
he must have believed in profit sharing. Had he remained faithful to that
principle, the wholesale society had been the promoter instead of the
organised discouragement of true co-operation.
Rochdale holds much of its old ground, and goes steadily forward in many
excellent ways, but the ancient enthusiasm—which pushed forward into new
paths, or fought its way back to the old principles, when driven out of
them by adverse votes—has not been maintained with equal conspicuousness
among the new generation of co-operators; else we should have seen the
great principle of self-helping industry vindicated in Rochdale before
this.
-XIX-
THE STORY OF THE CORN MILL.
THE murder of the equitable industrial principle
effected at Mitchell Hey by the seizure and perversion of the Co-operative
Manufacturing Society was noised abroad, and spread discouragement
throughout the earth. It was of the nature of a compliment to Rochdale,
that what was done in that town should be thought much of elsewhere.
Rochdale men had come to be considered as really pioneers of
industrial progress. The abandonment of co-operative principle in
the Manufacturing Society was treated as a "failure" of it. It was
supposed that the principle had been tried by deliberate, sagacious,
patient, earnest men, who had applied all their powers to it, exhausted
all their resources upon it, made prolonged sacrifices to give it effect,
had afforded ample time for the experiment to be fully
tested, and that the failure of the principle was decisive. It has
been shown now how mistaken all these impressions were. If the people of
Oldham can build a new mill every week, the increasing and enterprising
population of Rochdale might surely start other
manufacturing societies, and try the experiment again and again and
restore and increase the reputation of that historic town.
When I went to
the Industrial Exhibition at Amsterdam, owing to the interest taken in
it by Mr. Somerset Beaumont, M. P., the first question put to me by Baron
Mackay on the Commission of Inquiry, at which he presided, was, "Had the
Corn Mill failed?" The impression in Holland was that failure had set in
in Rochdale, and that whatsoever was equitable, fair, and hopeful, and of
good report, had been swallowed up by the impetuous dragon of unscrupulous
dividend.
The Corn Mill Society was founded, as has been related (Part I.), in 1850. An account of its first years, dated now sixteen years ago,
was written by Mr. W. Cooper. The Mill began in a dainty way. The
co-operators had acquired some taste by dealing at the Store, and had
learned to dislike as well as detect adulteration, and resolved to imitate
the successful example of Leeds, and have a corn
mill of their own. The rules were drawn up mainly by the same sagacious
hands which drew up the Pioneers' rules six years before (Mr. Charles
Howarth's), who was a factory worker, but was also a
kind of "sea lawyer" to the Pioneers. He would give his nights
to the humble work of codification. It took him a long time to see
his way; but he was sure to find it. He was one of those ocular men who
keep on looking until they see something.
The adventurous promoters of this Mill—though it is plain sailing now, it
was quite an affair of unknown navigation then—held their first
meetings, as we have said, at the Elephant and Castle Inn, Manchester
Road, Rochdale. Afterwards they met at the Weavers' Arms, and, finally, at
the meeting-room of the Pioneer Store, Toad Lane, that Society taking
twenty shares of £5 each in the Corn Mill. John Butterworth carried the
first treasury box, which, Mr. Cooper records, "was not very heavy, as it
seldom had more than £6 at a time in it." When a capital of £1000 was
provided, steps were taken to look out for a mill. At first an old one was
taken about a mile and a half from Rochdale, called "Holme Mill," at a
rental of
£150. Members brought in all the money they could. Among the first
committee were Laurence Melladay, Geo. Greenwood, John Turner, Edmund
Hartley, and John Butterworth, of the "treasury box," all of whom
subscribed to the extent of their means. Others put in only a
portion of their money, investing at the same time elsewhere, lest the
Corn Mill should grind up with the wheat what they had put in it.
Others helped the Corn Mill with their good wishes, waiting to see how it
succeeded before they helped it in any more expensive way. The Toad
Lane Pioneers, however, made an investment of £100 more—a good deal for
them to risk when their Society was only six years old. They
appointed representatives in whose name the money should be invested, a
plan afterwards followed by other societies—the plan being to give one
representative to every £5. Before the end of 1850, the Equitable
Pioneers had thirty representatives—quite a detachment—to look after
their £200. About a mile and a half from Rochdale existed a
Brickfield Equitable Pioneer Society. Though fewer in numbers than
the Rochdale Society, it was never behind in support of the Mill.
Its members were really what have since been called "bricks." They
appointed representatives and paid their investments, and when the Mill
got to work the Brickfield "bricks" bought all their flour from the
Mill—good or bad, none else would they sell. The Rochdale Equitable
Pioneers did the same.
Some persons who joined the Mill Society, conceived a clever
little scheme of getting some profit out of it. They proposed to take at a
rental a portion of the Holme Mill, with turning power for willows to
break up cotton or other waste. As this scheme promised to lessen the
risks of the Society by lessening its rental, all the timid members were
likely to be influenced by it; while others wisely contended that the
dust from the waste would get into the flour, and their customers might
reasonably object to eat a mixture of cotton waste and wheat. After
argument enough to turn a dozen corn mills, it was decided not to re-let.
The Pioneers' Almanac, in due course, set forth touching the
Corn Mill: "The objects of this Society are to provide for its members and
those who trade with it, pure, wholesome, and unadulterated flour at a
price and quality equal to what can be done by any miller in the
neighbourhood, and divide the profits arising from the trade amongst the
members, in proportion to the amount of money expended, having first paid
interest upon capital after the rate of five per cent. per annum." [54] The
laws by which the Society is governed are the same in principle as those
of the Equitable Pioneers, save in the exclusion of labour from profit.
In 1861, for the first time, the words "after the rate of five per cent.
per annum" were changed into "after the rate of £5 per cent. per annum."
The Toad Lane Store had been going sixteen years then, before it was
discovered that an abstract statement of financial profits was not
intelligible to the concrete minds of Rochdale. The increasing number of
outsiders who were beginning to come into the stores and buy of the Mill
did not quite understand what "five per cent." meant—they perfectly
understood what "£5" meant. It takes a long time to acquire the art of
making things plain.
Never was there a more obstinate corn mill than that of Holme. The
flour would not be good—the mill would not pay—and the profits would not
come. The first report of the Society was ashamed to show itself;
the second, of June, 1851, showed a loss of £103; the third report, of
September, showed a loss of £338 on the quarter's transactions. A
total loss of £441 attracted an army of croakers. Mr. Darwin would
have had no difficulty in tracing the
descent of all of them in a town which had produced Toad Lane. But the
croakers were not born round the mill. The Pioneers were said to be
blundering. It was plain to everybody they did not understand corn
milling. Their manager had mismanaged. The Society discharged him, and the
directors and president, Mr. Abraham Greenwood, went to market themselves,
taking a miller with them to judge the quality of the grain they bought,
and they managed without a manager.
A revolutionary meeting was held at the Pioneers' meeting-rooms, when the
prophets of evil were, as is their wont, eloquent in favour of running
away. Some members argued that they had better give up supporting the Corn
Mill; that the Store, by selling only the Corn Mill Society's flour, was
losing its custom; that the Corn Mill Society was losing money, and could
not be made to pay, and that the Mill would go down, and the Store had
better shake the Mill off, buy their flour wherever they could buy it
cheapest and best, else
the Mill would drag the Store down along with it. Others maintained that
private individuals could make it do, and get a fortune
out of the business, and why not co-operators? The causes of the losses
were shown to arise from shortness of money to work the business with,
necessitating them to take grain from those factors who would give them
credit, when sometimes that wheat was neither the best nor the cheapest;
from neglect or want of skill, or both, in the head miller; and from want
of better support from the members
and stores. It was also said by others that if the Corn Mill Society was
to fail, it would be a severe test for co-operation in Rochdale, for how
would confidence in the Rochdale Equitable Pioneers' Society be
maintained, when the members could be pointed to one
Co-operative Society in the town that had already failed? We have related
already how there came into play that vigorous sense and talismaniac faith
of the Pioneer idea. Mr. James Smithies contended that duty, the honour of
co-operation and pioneership, called upon
them not to forsake the Mill. A majority voted in favour of continuing it. Some of the opposition shook their heads, and said the
majority would not see their folly until they had brought ruin to the
"Pioneers' Society." But though the Corn Mill Society had got one
favourable vote in the Pioneers' Society, it was not yet safe; for an
unfavourable one might be passed at some other meeting of
the same Society. Parties went about enthusiastically crying the
Mill up, while others were hysterically crying it down. As the same
members belonged to the Corn Mill Committee and the Store Committee, they
had to run from one room to another to divert an
adverse vote. Mr. Cooper gives a picture of the social difficulty of doing
this—one of those transcripts of the domestic sacrifices of reformers
seldom brought into sight, though an important part of social history:—
"There were the monthly meetings of each of the societies, besides
occasional special meetings, and two officers had to attend
committee meetings one night, often more, in each week. Of course the men
would be away from home while attending these meetings. The wife, who is
mostly as good a supporter of the mill as her husband, generally putting
up with the flour when it was not so good as it ought to be; and when she
had a nice baking bread showing it to all neighbours and comers—that they
might be convinced what good
flour the Corn Mill Society was making. Certainly some husbands would find
fault with the wife when the bread was not good, and say 'she had spoiled
the flour,' to which some wives would reply, 'they could bake as well as
other people if they had the same flour, and that they would not use the
Corn Mill Society's flour if they were to be grumbled at because they
could not make good bread out
of bad flour.' The husband would be from home while attending meetings,
the wife had to put the children to bed, and would be waiting with no one
to speak a word to her, until the husband came
from the meeting. All would be silent except the constant tick of the
clock, the rain battering against the windows, and the wind whistling and
howling as if it had risen in revolt against the restraints imposed upon
it by nature. To the wife alone, minutes seem as long as hours, she thinks
she is neglected, her husband
attending meetings, or anything else rather than home. At another house
little Elizabeth has been sickly some days, and father has been at work
all day, and now, when his work is done, he has gone to the meeting. The
mother cannot get the child to rest—she
thinks it is getting worse. When the husband comes home, she tells him how
sickly the child is, and that he ought not to have gone to the
meeting—indeed, if he had any thought for the child he could
not go. He tells her he has come home as soon as the meeting was over, but
he cannot persuade her that he ought to have gone at all. He believes the
child will be better in a few days, and promises to
help her to nurse and take care of her till it is so. These, or many
similar incidents, will have occurred to most persons engaged in
promoting social or other reforms. But it must not be said that the women
are opposed to co-operation; they are and ever have been as much
interested and as zealous of its success as the men. There are many
instances where the husband was lukewarm and the wife could not prevail on
him to join the Co-operative Society, but she was not to be baffled, so
she enters the Co-operative Society herself. After a while, the husband thinks he should like to have his name on
the books. The wife will then withdraw so that he may take her number, or
he will be proposed, and they will both become members."
By the end of 1851 fifteen co-operative stores traded with the Corn Mill. By the end of 1852 they had increased to fifty-two. Among the individual
members of the Corn Mill, in its struggling days, were Mary Hawkes and
Elizabeth Stott, James Smithies, Abraham Greenwood, William Cooper, and
others familiar to the
reader. In the first year Samuel Ashworth, Thomas Barlow, John
Grindrod, John Collier, John Pickles, Edmund Hartley, George Holt, Edmund
Rhodes, John Clegg, and William Cooper had each £10 in the Mill, which
meant a good deal in those days.
There was real difficulty about the flour. Besides its sale not making
profit, it was not good—bad wheat being often bought; and when it was
really good, numbers of the customers disliked it. It was not so white as
that to which they had been accustomed.
They called it "yellow flour." It had a cream-coloured look, instead
of the nice alum colour with which they were familiar. They did not know
good flour when they saw it, and did not like it when they
tasted it. They had never known the taste of pure flour, and it took a
long time to educate their taste. In taking the falling fortune of the
Mill into his hands, Mr. A. Greenwood had to learn the art of buying wheat
and the trade of milling, and the proper
management of a flour mill. These difficult duties discharged, in addition
to those in a mill of a very different kind where he was employed, made
serious inroads both on his time and in his health.
For some years the consequences were serious to him. He, however,
succeeded in mastering the business, and pioneered the Mill
out of its difficulties. Mr. Robert Hoyle, Richard Hoyle, William Ellis,
William Taylor, and others, by enthusiasm and address aiding, it came to
pass that the first quarter in which the Society had no manager it made a
profit of £20.
We now arrive at the time, plain, tame, prosaic-looking 1855, when the
Weir Street Mill first entered into the human mind—that is into that part
of the human mind which understood co-operative enterprise in Rochdale. The fixed stock or fittings and machinery of the Holme Mill, where the
Corn Mill first commenced business, cost
£1,275. It really cost four shillings and a penny more (I mention the 4s.
1d. lest anyone should impugn the accuracy of this narrative). In the
early part of the Society's operations nothing could be set
aside for depreciation, owing to losses. When better days came, the losses
were cleared off, which was done before any dividend was
paid. At every subsequent report of the Society, £50 or £100, and
sometimes as much as £300, were set aside for wear and tear, and by the
end of 1855, everything had been paid for, excepting an amount of £27.
In 1856 a new mill and machinery was established at a cost of £6,827 16s.
10½d. (mark that "halfpenny!") The co-operators knew exactly what the
Corn Mill cost them. It has since been known as the "Rochdale District
Co-operative Corn Mill Society's New
Mill, Weir Street, Rochdale." According to the engraving which represents
it, and which I published at the Fleet-Street House, sixteen years ago, it
is the most melancholy mill that ever made a
dividend. Bark, thick, murky clouds around it, and the sky line
as grim as the ridges of a coffin. The white glass of the plain front
meets the eye like the ghost of a disembodied factory. A dreary waggon,
carrying bags of corn, guided by drivers that look like
mutes, is making its way through a cold, Siberian defile. The builder
might have made it pleasant to the eye, with as little expense as he made
it ugly. But in those days nobody thought of comeliness, seemliness, or
pleasantness in structure, in which men
would work all their lives. The really pleasant part about the Corn Mill
was in the minds of the gallant co-operators who set it going, and kept it
going.
The Almanac repeated that, "The objects of this Society are to provide its
members, and those who trade with it, with pure, wholesome, and
unadulterated flour. The profits arising from the trade are divided
amongst the members, in proportion to the amount of money expended, having
first paid interest upon capital (nothing
to the workmen) after the rate of £5 per cent. per annum. The laws by
which the Society is governed are the same in principle [which was not the
case] as those of the Equitable Pioneers."
The wise practice of reducing the cost of the mill by reserves made for
depreciation was continued, so that in 1860, when the mill could be sold
under the hammer for £6,000, it stood in the books as an asset at £3,862
only.
At the quarter ending June, 1860, the amount of business done at the
melancholy mill amounted to £33,140. The Directors then announced that "it
had then become obvious that their present mill and machinery could not be
extended much farther with advantage." At that time the number of members
was 550, the representatives
of stores and sick and burial societies included. It was for the benefit
of these societies that they should invest their accumulated funds in
co-operative undertaking; for, at the bank, they only obtained two or
three per cent, on their deposits, and they knew nothing
further about their money, except that they had left it there. Being men
of inquiring minds, they did not quite like this mystery about
their money. At the co-operative societies they could get five per cent.,
and know where their money was, and what it was doing, and have votes in
the management of the society, so as to make sure their
money was doing well. Of course, it took some trouble to persuade the
members of sick and burial societies that it was safe to invest
their funds in the Corn Mill. It was necessary that they should be
satisfied on this head, for if they had much anxiety about their money the
Directors themselves might become sick, and, being sick, not get better,
and then the Burial Society might have to inter the
Directors. When the Corn Mill had been some four or five years at work, a
lodge in the town took courage and voted to invest some of their money in
the Mill, and appointed three representatives to
take it. Mr. Cooper relates that, "when they got there and saw
the committee of the Mill they durst not leave the money." Perturbed,
confused, and not knowing how to explain their impressions, they retired
shambling, suspicious, and speechless. They went back to their lodge,
where they appeared like the Provost of Linlithgow, looking as though they
had been "touched by a torpedo, or seen of a wolf," and related that " they had beheld weavers
sitting on the Corn Mill committee, and that none of the committee were
rich men, so they had brought the money back to the lodge that it might be
safer than in the hands of working men." They had been swindled by
gentlemen before, as when the Savings Bank in the town failed, and brought
dismay into thousands of poor families; but they had never been swindled
by working men, and so they thought it a sort of duty to lose their money
by respectable defaulters only. The lodge, however, took a more
common-sense
view of the matter. They held a consultation upon the subject, and came to
the conclusion that weavers were as fit to be trusted as
bankers. They appointed fresh representatives with a little more courage,
and sent more money by them than they had entrusted to
the first downcast set. It was all invested, and ever after it remained.
In later years the Almanac gave this pleasant report of its progress:— "This Society, although one of the most delicate in its infancy, has now
grown to be one of the strongest and most healthy. About seven-eights of
the business done is with co-operative societies,
there being about 50 who trade with it. It supplies its members, and
others who trade with it, with pure, wholesome, unadulterated
flour meal. Some people have objected to the flour from this mill, simply
because, when supplied to them pure, it did not look so well to the eye
when baked into bread; we know that when they have
been most deceived they have been best pleased. Those who choose
to adulterate for themselves can do so. The gradually increasing business
has necessitated an increase in the productive power; consequently the
Society added in 1862 (to its previous working plant) one 25-horse-power
steam engine, and six pairs of French stones,
which are now at work helping to supply the increased demand. It has also
erected in the past year three cottage houses."
The difficulty about adulteration, which for a time was so serious, the
Society had quite overcome, and was even vivacious about it. The members
had become more intelligent; they had learned the nature of good flour
when they had it; their tastes were better educated than that of many
gentlemen of the middle class, and the Directors were able to tell the
purchasers, in a reckless manner, "if they wanted to adulterate the flour
they could do it themselves." The Society took upon themselves the
responsibility of advising the formation of corn mills in different parts
of the country where there were co-operative societies to support them. The propagandist sentiment has always been one of the honourable
distinctions of Rochdale. For this purpose they consulted Mr. John Holmes,
of Leeds, always a copious, fertile, quaint, and willing illustrator of
co-operative principles. He had had great experience with the
Leeds Corn Mill, of which he was a trustee. He explained that it may be
taken as a general fact that 1,000 families would not support a corn mill,
2,000 will probably do it, and 3,000 families would be
certain to do it. Of course this applied to demand alone. At Leeds
the mill would not have paid with 1,000 members. At Garforth, near Leeds,
where there were 1,500 members, the mill barely
existed. At Rochdale, they fared better with 2,000 members, but
then they sold to the public also. As to funds, the Leeds Society started
with 21s. per member, and with this 1,000 could trade. Perhaps with a mill
hired they might find machinery for 1,000 members for £2 each, or 2,000
for 30s, each; but for a freehold mill and works 2,000 people will require
50s. each, supposing all was
done well and cheaply. A mill could not be built, including ground and
machinery, for less than from five to seven thousand pounds,
to grind for 2,000 people.
The conclusion to which the Rochdale people came was, that in any district
where there are a group of co-operative stores not more than eight or ten
miles distant, having altogether three thousand members, and these
societies would furnish a capital of, say, 25s, per member, they would be
safe in renting a mill and fitting the same up with their own machinery. The cost would be greater now.
The progress and fluctuations of the "Rochdale District Cooperative Corn
Mill, Limited," is best told in its Almanac reports of 26 years.
Year |
Funds (£) |
Business (£) |
Profits (£) |
1850 |
|
None |
|
1851 |
2,613 |
* |
† None |
1852 |
2,898 |
7,636 |
336 |
1853 |
4,143 |
16,679 |
208 |
1854 |
3,971 |
22,047 |
557 |
1855 |
4,626 |
28,085 |
1,376 |
1856 |
8,784 |
38,070 |
773 |
1857 |
10,781 |
54,326 |
2,007 |
1858 |
14,181 |
59,188 |
3,135 |
1859 |
18,236 |
85,845 |
6,115 |
1860 |
26,618 |
133,125 |
10,164 |
1861 |
29,600 |
166,800 |
10,000 |
1862 |
30,254 |
155,696 |
8,227 |
1863 |
41,714 |
152,492 |
10,138 |
1864 |
46,739 |
141,309 |
7,806 |
1865 |
55,261 |
148,533 |
12,511 |
1866 |
72,020 |
224,122 |
18,163 |
1867 |
89,000 |
357,440 |
15,000 |
1868 |
86,400 |
349,439 |
4,824 |
1869 |
95,961 |
219,674 |
None |
1870 |
56,000 |
185,603 |
None |
1871 |
63,570 |
190,751 |
3,661 |
1872 |
64,692 |
215,238 |
3,133 |
1873 |
67,898 |
241,399 |
5,145 |
1874 |
71,294 |
244,181 |
6,474 |
1875 |
79,615 |
204,242 |
2,532 |
1876 |
77,279 |
176,671 |
3,370 |
1877 |
78,234 |
252,045 |
5,333 |
1878 |
83,985 |
285,920 |
3,860 |
1879 |
88,857 |
270,037 |
5,822 |
1880 |
97,414 |
301,835 |
7,989 |
1881 |
96,609 |
299,670 |
6,933 |
1882 |
99,885 |
286,968 |
2,144 |
1883 |
101,323 |
259,397 |
3,295 |
1884 |
101,850 |
209,910 |
1,543 |
1885 |
99,980 |
192,632 |
None |
1886 |
95,319 |
167,654 |
330 |
1887 |
87,868 |
148,726 |
None |
1888 |
88,198 |
183,524 |
44 |
1889 |
85,340 |
196,067 |
Loss, 2,642 |
1890 |
86,899 |
235,274 |
4,510 |
1891 |
93,122 |
315,598 |
9,022 |
1892 |
103,358 |
254,061 |
2,384 |
* Account mislaid
† Loss £441
______________________
[Next Page]
NOTES.
42. Co-operative News, December 18, 1876.
43.
The last communication I received from Mr. Cooper contained this cartoon;
underneath the sitters is the name of each written by Mr, Cooper. I have
it framed and it hangs in my chambers before me now.
44. Rochdale old church, as visitors to the town are aware, stands on an
abrupt hill, overlooking the borough; and at the foot of the hill runs the
Roach. It is among the dead on the plateau above where "Tim Bobbin"
lies, and old townsmen believe it was
on his grave that Mr. Bright made his first public speech in the town. He
was then a
young man. He had come down from One Ash, his father's house, to protest
against
levying a church rate. "Tim" must be very proud, if he knew it, that that
voice should first be heard over his head, which one day all the world
would hear.
Tim Bobbin's gravestone was put down and the verses on it composed long
after his death, by a distant relative. The stone, and the inscription on
it, has since been renewed by subscription. Mr. John Bright did not speak from it at the Church
Rate
meeting. The authority to whom I am indebted for this information,
stood by Mr. Bright on the top of one of the monuments in the old
churchyard, from which he addressed the assemblage. Mr. Bright could not have addressed them from Tim
Bobbin's stone, because it was not then raised above the level of the
churchyard, and he would
have been lost in the crowd, had he stood there. However, if the dead
hear at all, Mr. Bright was quite near enough for Tim to be aware of what
was going on.
45. History of
Co-operation in England, Vol. II., Constructive Period.
46. The editor of the
almanack has given this explanation of his views:—"We were charged with
'Socialism,' and 'Communism,' and these terms amongst most of the people
we wanted to reach were only synonymous with 'atheism' and 'social
anarchy.' We did not care for the shopkeepers we knew they would
always be against us from former experience; but there were the great mass
of the working people to whom we wanted to bring the benefits only a few
had tasted." Had the author of this passage confined himself to
pointing out that the Rochdale Pioneers were walking in a distinct though
coincident, path from that described by those eminent theorist—had he
pointed out that the Rochdale Co-operators were working in the same
direction of social improvement, of self-created, self-directed,
self-sustained, personal prosperity, which the great thinkers who inspired
them meditated, he had better defended weavers from injurious
misapprehension.
47. I wrote one for the
Hadderdfield Co-operators.
48. There was no great
"Wholesale" in those days. It had not even been debated at Jumbo
Farm.
49. Professor
Fawcett.—"Macmillan's Magazine," October, 1860.
50. All these profits as
we have said did not go into the shopkeepers' pockets. The
co-operator gets the savings by cash payments, no bad debts, by occupying
cheaper shops, making no display of gas, or of goods which perish by
exposure; by numerous customers and few servants; by buying wholesale;
advantages which small shopkeepers cannot command. Owing to his
greater expenses the shopkeeper does not get half the profit the
co-operator makes. It, therefore, creates needless ill-will to represent
that co-operative profits formerly went into the shopkeeper's pocket.
Co-operators often talk in this inaccurate way, and no wonder that a
writer new to the subject fell into the same language.
51. They first went round
August 11, 1860.
52. This is not
co-operation proper, because it treats capital as co-equal with labour,
making it a partner, instead of an agent merely. But co-operation
had got no further in that day.
53. Handbook of the
Rochdale Congress, 1892, by William Robertson.
54. This is so far the
right form of productive co-operation; it hires capital and divides
all profits among the purchasers who make it. But the Almanac is silent as
to including the workmen. |