[Previous Page]
CHAPTER XXVIII.
INDUSTRIAL PARTNERSHIP
"It is a natural and not an unreasonable wish for every man
to form that he should have some interest in, and some control over, the
work on which he is employed. It is human nature, I think, that a
man should like to feel that he is to be a gainer by any extra industry
that he may put forth, and that he should like to have some sense of
proprietorship in the shop, or mill, or whatever it may be, in which he
passes his days. And it is because the system introduced of late
years of co-operative industry meets that natural wish that I look forward
to its extension with so much hopefulness. I believe it is the best,
the surest remedy for that antagonism of labour and capital."—EARL
DERBY (then Lord Stanley) at
Opening of the Liverpool Trades Hall, October, 1869.
ONE form of Industrial Partnership is a business in
which the employers pay to the hands a portion of profits made in addition
to their wages, on the supposition that the men will create the said
profit by increased interest and assiduity in their work.
M. Le Comte de Paris, the author of a wise and readable book on Trades
Unions, describes "Co-operative Societies for production as transforming
the workman into a capitalist by securing to him a share of the profits of
the undertaking in which he has invested the capital of his labour." A
co-operative workshop does more, it divides not a share, but all the
profits among the producers. [209]
Earl Derby was distinguished among public men by the
faculty of seeing a question from which he may dissent from the point of
view of those who accept it; and such is his clearness of statement that
those who listen to him find their own case put as it were by themselves,
when they see it most completely and state it best to their own
satisfaction. The question of industrial partnerships is contained
in the following passage from the speech mentioned at the head of his
chapter:—
"In participation there are losses as
well as gains; but the very fact that these occur will make the men who
share in them understand and feel better than they ever did before the
responsibilities and the difficulties of the employer; and if, as is quite
possible, many having felt its difficulties, prefer the certainty and
security of fixed wages, they, at least, have had heir choice between the
two systems. It is quite probable that there are some trades, some
kinds of businesses in which it cannot be brought about; but it seems to
me that it is in that direction that the efforts of the best workers and
the ideas of the best thinkers are tending, and we are not to be
disheartened by a few failures, or disappointed because we do not at once
hit on the best way of doing what has never been done before."
Partnership in industry seems to have entered the Irish mind
before it did the English, if regard be had to legislative evidence.
In Dublin as early as 1788 there was "issued by George Grierson, printer
to the King's Most Excellent Majesty" (there has been a good deal of
Majesty since 1788 which has not appeared "Most Excellent" to anybody), an
"Act to promote Trade and Manufacture by regulating and encouraging
partnerships." The words "Chap. XLVI." were annexed thereto.
Its preamble set forth that "whereas the increasing the stock of money
employed in Trade and Manufacture must greatly promote the commerce and
prosperity of this kingdom, and many persons might be induced to subscribe
sums of money to men well qualified for trade (but not of competent
fortune to carry it on largely) if they (the subscribers) were allowed to
abide by the profit or loss of the trade for the same, and were not to be
deemed Traders on that account or subject hereby to any further or other
demands than the sums so subscribed." This is excellently put.
The whole theory of joint-stock partnerships is here. Mr. Schofield,
M.P. for Birmingham, when he carried his Bill in the English louse of
Commons eighty years later, could not have constructed a more relevant
preamble. Though valuable in its way, joint-stock partnership is not
Co-operation.
It was Mr. Owen, at Lanark, who first showed masters they
might, with honour and profit, do by voluntary partnership with those they
employed. The law did not permit participation of profit with workmen in
those days. It could only be done in the form of gifts. Only patronage
Co-operation was possible. Mr. Owen made these in the form of education,
recreation, improved dwellings, and increased wages. All these were revocable—the law forbade contracts
of participation with workmen. Industrial equity bore the name of
benevolence, and dividends of profit reached workmen in the form of a
discriminating charity.
Mr. Owen was a Paternalist. He believed in the general goodness of
humanity, and that goodness could guide it; but he had no conviction that
it could guide itself.
Industrial Partnerships owe to Fourier the principle of making labour
attractive instead of repulsive, and of distributing the profits in
proportion to the capital, skill, and labour, contributed by each;
Fourier made definite the idea of labour becoming the partner of capital,
instead of merely its servant.
It is, however, to the practical genius of an
Englishman, Mr. Charles Babbage, that we owe the earliest proposal, made
by a writer of repute in England, in favour of workmen being associated as
participators in the profits of a manufactory. On the south coast of
England it was known that one-half of all the fish caught belonged to the
owner of the boat and the net, the other half being divided in equal
portions among the fishermen using the net and boat, they being bound to
make repairs when needed. Cornish miners were paid in proportion to
the richness and produce of the vein worked. Thus they naturally
became quick-sighted in the discovery of lodes and in estimating their
value, and it was their interest to avail themselves of every improvement
in bringing the ore cheaply to the surface; Mr. Babbage therefore argued
that if some joint participation of profit in manufactures was devised,
the result of such arrangement would be:—
1. That every person engaged in it would have a direct interest in its
prosperity; since the effect of any success would almost immediately
produce a corresponding change in his own receipts.
2. Every person in the factory would have an immediate interest in
preventing any waste or mismanagement in all the departments.
3. The talent of all connected with it would be strongly directed to its
improvement.
4. When any additional hands were required, it would be the common
interest of all to admit only the most skilful; and it would be far less
easy to impose upon a dozen workmen than upon the single proprietor of a
factory.
5. And by no means least, there would be removed, by common consent, the
causes which compel men to combine for their own separate interests.
It is said an Englishman never knows when he is beaten, but a workman of
any sense does know when he has won, or when fairness of an employer has
conceded to him the opportunity of benefit in the trade in which he is
engaged. So that there would exist a union between employer and workman to
overcome common difficulties and promote a common interest. Lieutenant
Babbage, in a letter which I had the pleasure to receive from him, says
that his father advised co-operative manufactories, as the chapter in his
work shows, entitled "A New Manufacturing System."
Mr. Babbage's wise scheme met with very scant co-operative recognition. The Editor of the
New Moral World saw no good that was likely to come of
industrial partnerships. The scheme which has attained ascendancy and
rendered great service to the working class, was dismissed with these
discouraging editorial words, "As a temporary expedient we are very
doubtful of the value of Mr. Babbage's plan, while as an adequate
amelioration of the condition of the industrious classes, we can have no
faith in schemes that render them dependent for subsistence on the chances
of employment" [210]
The Chartists among the working class thought Free Trade a Whig scheme to
deceive them; Trade Unionists suspected it as a contrivance to get more
work out of them. No attention was paid by any manufacturer to this
sensible and well-put plan. Mr. Babbage might as well have spoken down a
well, as far any response was concerned. Nobody then had any real
confidence in mutual relations between
capital and labour. But it remains an encouraging fact that great
mathematician should give the actual details of the industrial policy of
the future as exact as the calculation of the appearance of a new planet.
In some cases employers pay large wages from pure goodwill to their men,
or provide news-rooms, or dining-rooms, or schools, or provide them with
good habitations at low rents, or pension old workmen, or contribute to
provident or other societies for their personal advantage. Such employers
do virtually establish an industrial partnership, of goodwill though not
of right.
Lord Brassey evidently takes more than his father's interest in the
commercial welfare and industrial security of the working class. He
pointed out in his Halifax address how it comes to pass that "the rich,
gathering themselves together in the most eligible situation in every
town, the price of land becomes so enormous that it is impossible to erect
houses at rates which, while not exceeding what workmen can afford to pay,
will be remunerative to the owners and builders. Hence the working class
are compelled
to occupy more remote suburbs. They live in daily contact with no other
class but their own, and a consequent danger is incurred of social
disunion. This state of things is practically inevitable under our
existing system." Then the existing system requires altering. In the town
of Leicester the wealthier portion of the population have taken possession
of all the higher and salubrious parts, and the poor have no choice but to
live in the lower and unhealthier. Mr. Stansfeld, M.P., had in view to
introduce a Bill to enable corporations to acquire land, in the vicinity
of large towns, so as to secure the poorer population some opportunity of
healthy existence. Undoubtedly "the tendency of modern industry," as Lord Brassey remarks, "has been, and will continue to be, towards the
concentration of capital in large
corporate or private establishments." There must be contrived some
participation of these inexorable and unhinderable profits among the
artisan class; else the many will have no choice but to combine against
the few, and stop in some disagreeable
way that which stops them from existing endurably. [211] Common people
increasing in intelligence cannot be expected to perish in the sight of
ever-increasing affluence, and die gratis.
The saying that "it is liberty which is old, and despotism which is new,"
oft recurs to a writer on industrial welfare. It seems a new thing to
propose now that employers should be studious to provide for the welfare
of those who labour. In Egypt the pyramids endure; the huts of the
Fellahs, of the makers of bricks, have been destroyed and renewed a
thousand times since Pentaour watched their misery. But other ancient
nations showed noble regard for workmen. At Mocke the great pyramid of the
Chimus remains built by the ancient Peruvians. The mighty Peruvian pyramid
still stands imposing in its decay, and by it equally remain, no less
permanent, the dwellings of the masons and metal workers, "organised,"
says a recent explorer, "with an order and a system which a Socialist phalanstery might despair of rivalling." [212] In all the dominions which the
Incas ruled as monarchs or suzerains, this combination of love of display
and care for the well-being of the humblest subjects, speaks of a wise
consideration for the people.
A "sentimental" man is one who does what is right because it ought to be
done. A "practical" man is one who
does what is right because it pays. The practical man I respect
because
he raises Co-operation into the region in which it can live. The
sentimental man I honour because he raises Co-operation above the region
of dividends into the nobler region where the indispensable pursuit of
gain is purified by the loftier feeling of duty. There are those who think
a man "practical" who gets dividends anyhow. He who willingly does wrong
because it pays, is a fool or a rascal. He may profit by it, but he fills
his little money-bag with a scoundrel shovel; and the executive business
of perdition will be very badly managed if there be not somebody's
janissary on the other side the grave waiting for these knaves. Sentiment
is as yet unmacadamised ground, and some stumble thereon. There is all the
difference between light and twilight—of pursuing equity from a sense of
justice and pursuing it for mere gain.
Political economists, with a perspicacity unexercised
until lately, now discern that "all extra remuneration that is awarded to
labour in excess of the wages that are earned by labour is, in reality,
given, not for the pure or simple labour itself, but for the greater
skill, ability, knowledge, or intelligence with which it is accompanied;
and these additional qualifications which accompany labour are regarded by
Adam Smith as a species of capital that is fixed and realised in the
persons of those who possessed them, and the value of which is to be
estimated by their worth in simple labour." [213]
"Some years ago," says Dr. Doherty, "it was reported in the public press
that a great saving of coke had been effected by the managers of the
Belgian railways; the work formerly done by ninety-five tons now being
accomplished with forty-eight tons. And this is the way in which the
saving was made. It was known that the men who used the coke to heat the
locomotives on the line were not careful of the fuel. Ninety-five kilogrammes of coke were consumed for every league of distance run, but
this was known to be more than necessary; but how to remedy the evil was
the problem. A bonus of 3.½d. on every hectolitre of coke saved on this
average of ninety-five to the league was offered to the men concerned, and
this trifling bonus worked the miracle. The work was done equally well, or
better, with forty-eight kilogrammes of coke, instead of ninety-five;
nearly one-half, saved by careful work, at an expense of probably less
than one-tenth of the saving." [214]
Mr. Thomas Hughes, writing to the Pall Mall Gazette, in reply to an
article which suggested that if no profits were made at Methly there would
be no means of paying the labourers, who while they would share the
profits would not stand to any of the losses, remarks that "In the first
Year of the partnership a very considerable surplus profit may be made. By
the articles, the board of directors—consisting of the former employers
and several of their foremen—have the power of setting apart and
investing a large proportion of these profits as a reserve fund, which may
be used at any time in aid of wages or in making up the fixed interest on
invested capital in future years. If this power is exercised, and the
first year or so is profitable I think the danger is overcome. I believe
that as a rule the periods are not long during which a properly managed
business does not return enough to pay the average rate of wages, and the
interest on capital usual in the trade, be it 7 or 10, or 15 per cent. The
reserve fund once established may fairly be looked to, to enable the
partnership to tide over these slack times without a reduction of the
wages of labour or the fixed interest on capital."
Lord George Manners, who projected an industrial partnership on his farm,
answered a similar objection. He said, "True, I may have to pay wages some
years when there has been a loss, but I do not forget that the best work
the labourers could do may have decreased that loss, and in other years
have increased my profits materially." This implied a generous feeling and
perfect perception of the question.
In Leicester, at a "Treat" given by Messrs. W. Corah & Sons, hosiery
manufacturers, to 450 of their workpeople, one of the firm said: "Masters are making profits, and it was nothing but right that those who
worked for them should enjoy as far as possible their share of the profits
(cheers). He took it that there were respective duties for employers." In
the same town there are other employers who equally exemplify the sense of
industrial equity. In the North capital as a rule bites. In Midland
England it is friendly in tone to the workman. In Leicester Michael Wright
& Sons made a deliberate effort to introduce the principles of industrial
partnership into their Elastic Web Works, but did not find their efforts
supported by their workpeople. In the same town Messrs. Gimson & Co.
introduced it into their large engine works. They adopted the wise plan of
first entrusting its operation to a selection of their leading workmen, to
whom they offered the advantage of a share of the profits after the
attainment of a fair dividend upon capital. To these selected workmen was
left the power or nominating other workmen whom they discerned to be
capable and willing to increase the prosperity of the company by zeal and
judgment in the discharge of their duties.
This plan had the advantage of limiting the division of profits to those
who showed increased efforts in augmenting them, and
left the responsibility of excluding the indifferent to their fellow-workmen. Thus the opportunity was
fairly given, and it depended upon the men to make the arrangement
permanent by making it profitable. [215]
Before an employer takes this step he values his entire plant, and
prescribes the interest it ought to yield him on the average. It is the
surplus that may arise above this that he proposes to share with his men. Whether he will do this is a matter of calculation and good sense. He
knows that if a workman has no interest in the business beyond his
stipulated wages, he requires to be timed and watched; he adopts the
easiest processes; he cares nothing to economise material; he has small
pride in his work, and little concern for the reputation or fortune of the
firm in whose employ he is. He changes his situation whenever he can
better himself, leaving his master to supply his place as he may by a
strange hand, who loses time in familiarising himself with the
arrangements of a workshop new to him, or blunders, or destroys property
for the want of special local experience. If the workman has no chance of
changing his place for a better, he engages in strikes, imperils the
capital and endangers the business of his master. If his strike succeeds,
his master dislikes him because of the loss and humiliation he has
suffered. If his strike fails, the workman
is poorer in means and sourer in spirit. He works only from necessity; he
hates his employer with all his heart; he does him all the mischief and
makes all the waste he safely can. He gives his ear to alien counsellors,
and conspires and waits for the day when he can strike again with more
success. If an employer has a taste for this disreputable conflict he can
have it. If he does not like it he can prevent it. The newly-made
middle-class gentleman is prone to say, "What
is my neighbour to me?" It is enough for him that his neighbour does not
annoy him or does not want to borrow anything from him, nor create any
nuisance upon adjacent premises which may reach to him. Beyond this he
thinks very little about his neighbour, and will live beside him for years
and never know him, nor want to know co-operative thinker sees in his
neighbour a person whom it pays to know. He has a social idea in his mind,
which is not merely kindliness, it is worth money.
Charles Frederick Abel became chamber musician to the Queen of George
III., because none but he could play upon the viola de gamba (a small
violoncello with six strings) with equal perfection. Afterwards came Paganini, who entranced nations by the melody concealed in a solitary
cord. It was genius in him to discover and display it. We
have not yet explored all the mysteries of cat-gut; yet capitalists would
assure us that they have sounded all the compass of the most wonderful of
all instruments—man; whereas the employer of labour chiefly knows man as
an available animal who trots under the whip, or as a hired machine of
reluctant action. The workman has skill and good-will, contriving, saving,
and perfecting qualities, which are never enlisted where one man is a mere
instrument bound to fidelity only by the tenure of starvation—designing
to desert his employer, and the employer intending to dismiss him the
moment either can do without the other. Industrial partnership is a policy
of buying the skill and will of a man—his genius and his self-respect,
which elevate industry into a pursuit of art, and service into
companionship. It is a scheme of reciprocity. An industrial partnership is
but a superior business arrangement.
But co-operators can make better partnerships for themselves by
establishing workshops of their own. To supplicate for them would simply
give employers the idea that some charity was sought at their hands. They
can be obtained by combination. Trade unions are the available means for
this purpose. At the Social Science Congress held in Leeds in 1871 I said
in the Economy Section, over which Mr. Newmarch presided, that the working
classes should be in that position in which they should neither supplicate
nor
depend upon the will of their masters. What they had no right to, no
entreaty should obtain for them. What they had a right to, they
should be in a position to command. The conception of working a mine
the French express by the word exploiter. By the phrase l'exploitation de
l'homme par l'homme is meant that a capitalist uses a man and works a
man as he works a mine; he gets all he can out of him. There is no great
objection to this so long as the man likes it. Where, however, these
partnerships are volunteered, that is a different thing, and too much
regard or honour cannot be paid to those whence the offer comes. A speech
quite as important as that of Lord Derby's, considering the rank of the
gentleman who made it, is of this nature, I mean the speech which the
Right Hon. Mr. Brand, Speaker of the House of Commons, addressed to his
labourers at Glynde. He said, "We shall never come to a satisfactory
settlement of the relations between employer and employed until the
employed, according to the amount of labour and capital he has invested in
the concern, is interested in the good conduct of that concern."
One merit of this speech was that it was followed by a plan for
practically enabling his labourers to become shareholders in the estate at
Glynde. The language and the example are alike important. To admit
labourers as part-proprietors of the Glynde estate, confers upon them a
position of pride and self-respect as valuable as it is new. Such
admission, rightly used, would produce more advantages than many
agitations, such as are within the means of labourers to conduct. To have
it admitted by a gentleman so eminent and influential as the
representative of the House of Commons, that labourers had a social right
to share in the profits of the estate which they contributed to cultivate,
was an admission of more service to the working people than many Acts of
Parliament passed in their name, and professedly for their benefit. For an
humble villager to be able to say that he was a shareholder in the Glynde
estate, however small might be the portion which his prudence and
frugality enabled him to acquire, however small might be the profits thus
accruing to him, his position was entirely changed. His forefathers were
slaves, then serfs, then hired labourers. He becomes in some sort a
landowner. He henceforth
stands upon what Lord Cockburn would call a "colourable" equality with the
proprietor himself. If he had any cultivated spirit of independence in
him, such labourer would have more satisfaction in the idea, than many a
tenant farmer is
able to find in the position which he holds. It must follow in a few years
that the wages of such a man must increase, and by prudence, temper, and
good judgment the relation between this body of small proprietors and the
chief owner
must be pleasant and honourable. That these labourers were wanting in the
disposition, or were ill advised by those to whom they would naturally
look for counsel, and neglected to act on the unusual offer made by Mr.
Brand, detracts in no way from the value of it. Men may be taken to the
steps of Paradise, and decline to ascend, yet he is not the less
meritorious who gives them the opportunity. A man may not have the sense
to ascend—he may not understand his opportunity—he may even distrust it,
or think it too insignificant to trouble about, he may have the humility
which makes him doubt his own fitness to advance, he may have the
diffidence which makes him distrust his own power of going forward, he may
even prefer to remain where he is, content that he may advance on another
occasion; but he is no longer the same man, he stands higher in his own
esteem if he has any self-respect. He has had the chance of better things,
and the old feeling of discontent and sense of exclusion and bitterness at
his precarious state are changed, and an inspiration of manliness,
equality, and undefined satisfaction takes the place of his former
feelings. A man may have a great opportunity, and for some preference or
infatuation of his own he may go past it; he may regret it, but he is
happier than he who never had the chance of bettering himself. So every
manufacturer and every landowner who makes overtures of industrial
partnership to his men, raises the character of mastership and
proprietorship; sooner or later men will accept the offers, and be
grateful for them, and turn them to fortunate account. In the meantime,
the whole temper of industry is being changed by these overtures; the
mighty doors of conciliation and equality are being opened, through which,
one day, all the workmen of England will pass.
In the meantime the mere dream of this invests the order of industry with
new interest and hope. This will seem sentimental only to those who know
human nature second hand. We all live in ideals. Those who deny the ideal
of
others live in one of their own—lower or higher. The true artist,
solitary and needy though he may be, paints for the truth, the thinker
thinks for it, the martyr dies for it, the
glory of which only his eye sees. Progress is the mark of humanity. The
aspiration even of the lowest is the ideal which carries him forward; and
when it fails, manhood perishes.
Co-operation has filled the air with ideas of progress by concert. Men
thought the flashes of lightning which play upon the fringe of a coming
tempest, were the rainbow arch which denotes a permanent truce between the
warring elements, a sign that the storm is passing away.
CHAPTER XXIX.
INDUSTRIAL CONSPIRACIES
"My opinion is, we shall never have a satisfactory
settlement of the wages question until the labourer receives in some shape
or other a share of the profit of the business in which he is engaged.
I refer not only to those employed upon farms, but to those engaged in
mining, in manufactories, and in trades of all kinds."—The Right Hon.
Mr. Brand's (Speaker of the House of Commons) Speech to Labourers at
Glynde, 1876.
HAD declarations of opinion like that of Lord
Hampden, above cited, been acted upon by employers, industrial
conspiracies, the "conflicts of capital and labour," would not have
existed.
A conspiracy is a secret scheme for attaining certain
advantages by coercion. Modern trades unions have been mostly of
this kind, the object being, in their case, increase of wages.
Co-operation is not a conspiracy, it is a concerted industrial
arrangement, open and legitimate, with a view to place moderate competence
within the reach of workmen and—keep it there. The end sought by
unionists and co-operators is practically the same; the means of its
attainment being different is no intrinsic ground of antagonism between
them. Because two companies of excursionists to the same place
choose to go, one on foot and the other by railway, is no reason for their
hating each other on the road, and not associating at the end of their
journey. Nor if any of the walking party become foot-sore, is there
any reason why they should not be invited to come into the train at the
first station.
The co-operators imagine themselves to have adopted the
easier, cheaper, and speedier way of reaching the pleasant territory of
competence. They lose no money on the road, they even make what
money they expend productive. They do not annoy masters, nor
petition them for increase of wages, nor wait upon them, nor send
deputations to them, nor negotiate with them—they make themselves
masters. They supply or hire their own capital, they fix their own
wages, and, as has been said, divide the whole of the available profits
among themselves. Thus they attain increase of income without
strikes, or incurring absolute loss of money by paying men to be idle.
I am not among those who consider money wasted on strikes. It is an
investment in resistance to inequitable payment, which brings return in
increased manliness if not in increased wages. At the same time it
must be owned there is loss of capital in it. The masters' profits
and men's savings spent in strikes, disappear as though they were thrown
into the sea. A strike is war, and all war is loss of the material
means of the combatants. Therefore the co-operator, whose mind turns
mainly upon the hinge of economy, holds that employers, when unfair or
aggressive, are to be superseded, not combated. The superseding
process has more dignity and costs less. It a gentleman has cause of
complaint against a neighbour, an associate, or a stranger, he explains
the matter to him, asks for what in reason he has a right to ask, taking
care himself neither to be impatient nor give just cause of offence in his
manner of putting his case, and if he fail to obtain redress he avoids the
person and takes what steps he can to render it impossible that he shall
be treated in a similar manner again. This is the co-operative plan
of dealing with too exacting middlemen or inconsiderate employers.
Nobody quarrels but the bully who has an object in it, or the incapable,
who do not know how to put themselves right, except by the primitive
expedients of the savage or the washerwoman, by the use of the tomahawk or
the tongs.
Just as there would be a good deal of reverence in the world
were it not for theologians, so there would be more peace and better
understanding between adversaries were it not for conciliators. Conciliators are often disagreeable persons who, having no sympathy for
either side, see "faults on both," or, having a predilection for one
party, lectures the other upon the good sense of giving way to it. Conciliation is like charity, it is irrelevant where justice is needed—it
is offensive where justice is refused.
A combination of workmen to increase their wages is called "a conspiracy,"
while a similar combination of employers passes under the pleasant
description of "a meeting of masters to promote the interests of trade."
Trades unions of the guilds came first. Modern unions grew by a sort of
political instinct. It came to be seen that it was not by revolution that
the poor
could fight their forlorn and frantic way to competence, nor could they in
isolation
alter the constitution of society. In some faint and perplexing way it was
discovered to them that by combination they might acquire redress. Many
could resist where the few were crushed; and combination did not require
money—only sense. The poorest could unite. It cost nothing to cohere, and
cohering was strength, strength was resistance, resistance was money, for
thus higher wages came. True, the gain to one set of workmen often
proves a serious cost to others, as when masons compel higher wages they
put up the house rents of all the poor in the town, and make it more
difficult
for an artisan to build a house. Yet it was an advantage to the feeble to
learn that combination was power, its right use is the second step.
So little attention has been given by historians to projects of the people
for protecting their industrial interests, that it is difficult to tell
how early trades
unions, such as we now know them, began in England. Ebenezer Elliott told
me he believed that the ancient industrial guilds arose in efforts of
workpeople
to forefend themselves and dignify labour, by creating for it rights which
might enable it to raise its head under the contempt of gentlemen and
insolence of
the military spirit. Dr. John Alfred Langford—who has himself helped to
raise the character of the industrial class by the persistence with which
he, a
member of it, has acquired knowledge, and the ability with which he has
used it—relates in his "A Century of Birmingham Life" curious particulars
of an
early conspiracy of needlemen in that active town. The needlemen of
Birmingham always knew how to sew ideas together as well
as fabrics. If their strike of more than 128 years ago was the
first one, strikes came to perfection early. Unionists turn to
Co-operation in self-defence, showing a mastery of resources
not common to this time. In Dr. Langford's pages we learn that in Swinney's Chronicle of February 13, 1777, the master tailors of
Birmingham advertised for 100 hands, who were sure to be able to earn 16s.
a
week. They were to apply to William Moyston, 130, Moor Street, in that
town. As the war with America was then about over, many thought that a
nude tribe
of Red Indians had arrived in Birmingham and
needed clothing at a short notice. Four days later the mystery was
explained by a notice to "journeymen Taylors" signed by George Hanley,
telling the
public "The statement of the masters was false," and that "the prices were
stipulated so that he must be an extraordinary hand to get 12s.," and for
that
reason they were "all out of work." The masters rejoined by asking for "40
or 50 journeymen taylors to work piece-work, holding out prospects of 16s.
to 18s. per week." The applicants "were not to be subject to the House
of Call, as none would be employed but such as called at the masters'
houses
and are free from all combinations." It appears, therefore, that
"combinations" must have been common then, and the masters' restrictions
were
precisely what we hear of to-day. The journeymen in their turn appealed to
the public, whose
sympathy was with the men. They said they "objected to
piece-work on the ground of their late suffering by it." They defended
their "House of Call as an ancient custom both in London and all other
capital
towns," and announced "that they had joined together in order to carry on
their trade in all its different branches, and that good workmen and those
only
who applied at their House of Call at the "Coach and Horses," in Bell
Street, would meet with good encouragement." By "hunting the country
round" all the
masters obtained were "inexperienced lads," whereas the tailors on strike
were able to serve gentlemen well. Thus in Birmingham near 130
years ago a co-operative workshop was devised as the sequel of a strike. It is the first instance known. Trades unions in England as this century
has
known them, were not the device of policy but the offsprings of instinct
and courage. There were splendid trades unions in the days of the English
guilds. Nor would they have arisen again save that men were inspired with boldness
by political teachers, and began to combine to offer some resistance. They
little thought of demanding higher wages—they thought it a great
triumph to prevent theirs being lowered. The fable of the bundle of sticks
struck them as it did the poor co-operators
as a very original story. As one set of workmen after another faggoted
themselves together, the humble and familiar symbol of the tied sticks
appeared in their trade journals, and was
soon carried on their banners. Then combination laws were passed against
the struggling unionists. Those who did not get imprisoned or
transported like the Dorchester labourers, were told that what they sought
was all of no use: supply and demand had been discovered, and in case
these
failed, the labourer could not be sufficiently grateful that a poor-house
had been provided for him, as the workhouse master told the dying pauper
who
presumed to want to see the
clergyman—that "he ought to be glad he had a hell to
go to." [216] Still
the workman clung to his union, feeling, but not knowing how to explain
it, as Mr. Roebuck subsequently did. This is the unionist case as
put by that master of statement:—
"The working man, single-handed, as compared with the master, is a weak
and impotent being. The master has him in his own hands, can do with him
what he likes, give him what wages he pleases; for there are a large
number of persons outside wishing to be employed—labour is cheap and
plentiful; and
the master decides that he will give the men low wages. There are 200 or
2,000 men working together, and they say one to another, 'Let us act as
one
man.' They bring the whole body of workmen to bear as one man on the
master. Let there be equality on both sides, the working man having the
benefit of
the only capital he possesses, viz., his labour; and the master having the
benefit of that which is absolutely necessary to production—his capital."
Now everybody admits the right of the workman to combine; but those who
admit the right deny its utility, and contend that the workmen had better
leave
things to take their course, and wages would rise of themselves. Since,
however, employers and merchants who say this are observed never to wait
for prices to rise of themselves but combine to help them upwards, the
workman came to the conclusion that he had
better combine to quicken wages in their laggard movement towards
elevation.
Any one can see that combination is a distant power, only reached by many
steps; confidence, organisation, and discipline are some of them. The
working people have conspired in many ways, according to their knowledge. The reason why political philanthropists have always made it their chief
object
to promote the education of the poorest class in the State, was their
perceiving that workmen would one day expect the exhortations to frugality
and
prudence, given them by their "betters," to be followed by their "betters," and insist upon it being followed. When Mr. Malthus and the
Political Economists
began their protests against the large families of the poor, wise and
friendly protests as they were, the day was sure to come when the poor in
turn would
protest against the large families of the rich, whom the indigent would
know had
to be provided for at their expense. If the labourer is to be frugal, and
live upon his small income without debt, or need of charity in sickness,
he will be
sure to wonder, one day, why those who admonish him should need mansions,
parks, carriages, and footmen. Unless the poor are kept absolutely
ignorant and stupid, no man can advise frugality to poverty without those
who receive the advice expecting that he who gives it will follow it
himself. All
monitorial improvement of the lower class must end in enforcing a
corresponding improvement in the upper classes. These ebullitions of sense
on the
part of the working classes are very infrequent in their history. I have
met with only two or three instances, long forgotten now and buried in the
obscure
pamphlets of 1832. Their relevance, however, is not gone, and the vigour
of the argument, forcible beyond the defamatory invective on which feeble
agitators so commonly rely. When Mr. Joseph Pease, of the firm of Pease &
Co., worsted manufacturers at Darlington, one of the Society of Friends,
and
a strenuous member of the Anti-Slavery Society, was a candidate for the
southern division of the county of Durham, he issued an address to the
electors,
in which he said, "In all measures for the amelioration of our kind in
striking off the chains of slavery and mental darkness, in restraining the
oppressor, and
in turning the attention of a Christian Legislature to Christian
principles, I would be ardent and exertive." Whereupon a little piecer
in his factory was sent to him, with this little infantile speech in her
hand:—
"Good master, let a little child, a piecer in your factory
From early dawn to dewy eve—relate her simple history.
Before I came to work for you, my heart was full of mirth and glee;
I play'd and laugh'd, and ran about, no kitten was so blythe as me.
But just when I was eight years old, poor mother, press'd with want and
woe,
Took me one morning by the hand, and said, 'To factory thou must
go.'
They thrust me in and shut the door, 'midst rattling wheels and noisy din,
And in the frame gait made me stand, to learn the art of piecen-ing.
I often hurt my little hands, and made my tender fingers bleed,
When piecing threads and stopping flys, and thought 'twas very hard
indeed.
The overlooker pass'd me oft, and when he cried, 'An end down there,'
My little heart did tremble so, I almost tumbled down with fear.
When at the weary evening's close I could not keep myself awake,
He sometimes strapp'd me till I cry'd as if my little heart would break.
Oh, master! did you know the half that we endure, to gain you gold
Your heart might tremble for the day when that sad tale must all be told.
Ah! then I thought of days gone by, when, far from spindles, din, and
heat,
I deck'd my little giddy brow with buttercups and violets sweet.
From year to year I sigh in vain, for time to play,
and time to read.
We come so soon, and leave so late, that nought we know but mill and bed.
They tell us you grow very rich, by little piec'ners such as me,
And that you're going to Parliament, to guard our laws and liberty,
They say you pity Negro Slaves, and vow, oppressors to restrain,
To break the chains of ignorance, and Christian Principles maintain.
Oh! when you're there remember us, whilst at your frames we labour still,
And give your best support and aid to Mr. Saddler's Ten Hours Bill.
The poor, we know, must work for bread, but, master, are not we too young?
Yet if such little ones must work, pray do not work us quite so long!
Your 'Christian Principles' now prove, and hearken to the piec'ners
prayer,
Soon Christ in judgment shall appear, remember, you must meet us there."
[217] |
The other instance occurred in 1833, when Mr. H. Warburton had introduced
what was known as the Anatomy Bill, called in Yorkshire the "Paupers'
Dead
Body Bill," which provided subjects out of the poor-house for doctors to
cut up. As the wives and families of workmen in those days had no prospect
before them but that of ending their days in the poor-house, they did not
like this Bill, which they believed was intended to bring them all to the
dissecting-room. At the same time, Mr. Wilson Patten, instead of
supporting the Ten
Hours Bill, which the poor people believed would render pauper subjects
scarce, had proposed a commission to inquire into Factory labour, but that
subject, they thought, had been
inquired into enough, and they thought the Commission a trick intended to
delay passing the Bill. It is a custom of Parliament when people are mad
and
perishing for lack of some long-denied amelioration, to appoint a "Royal
Commission" to inquire whether they want it. The young
girl piecers, or the "pieceners," as they sometimes called
themselves, addressed a letter to Mr. Wilson Patten, M.P. It was
shorter than the previous address, somewhat more lyrical, but quite as
much to the purpose in its way. It ran thus:—
"Have you no children of your own,
Cold-hearted Wilson Patten?
We wish you'd send Miss Pattens down
All decked in silk and satin.
Just let them work a month with us,
And 'doff' their nice apparel;
And 'don' their 'brats' like one of us—
We promise not to quarrel.
We'll curtsey low—say 'Ma'am' and 'Miss,'
And teach them how to 'piece,' Sir;
They shan't be strapt when aught's amiss,
They shan't be treated rough, Sir.
We'll call them up at 'five o'clock,'
When all is dark and dreary;
No miller rude, their tears shall mock,
Nor vex them when they're weary.
We'll guard them home when work is done,
At seven or eight at night, Sir,
We'll cheer them with our harmless fun,
And never show our spite, Sir.
And when they've wrought a month at mill,
If they do not petition
For us to have the Ten Hour Bill,
THEN SEND US YOUR
'COMMISSION."' |
In Frazer's Magazine at this period attention was called to the evidence
of Mr. Gilbert Sharpe, the overseer of Keighley, Yorkshire, who was
examined by
the Factory Commission. He was asked whether he had any reason to think
that any
children lost their lives in consequence of excessive work in the mills. He said he had no doubt of it, and he gave this
instance. "Four or five months back, there was a girl of a poor man's
that I was called to visit; she was poorly—she had attended a mill, and I
was obliged
to relieve the father in the course of my office, in consequence of the
bad health of the child; by and by she went back to her work again, and
one day he
came to me with tears in his eyes. I said, 'What is the
matter, Thomas?' He said, 'My little girl is dead.' I
said, 'When did she die?' He said, 'In the night; and what breaks my
heart is this: she went to the mill in the morning; she was not able to
do work,
and a little boy said he would assist her if she would give him a
halfpenny on
Saturday; I said I would give him a penny." But at night, when the child
went home, perhaps about a quarter of a mile, in going home she fell down
several times on the road through exhaustion, till at length she reached
her father's door with difficulty.
Verse-writers with more or less skill put these facts
into song. Here are two of the stanzas enforcing the argument of
contrast of condition:—
All night with tortured feeling,
He watch'd his speechless child;
While close beside her kneeling,
She knew him not—nor smil'd.
Again the factory's ringing,
Her last perception's tried;
When, from her straw-bed springing,
'Tis time!' she shriek'd and died!
That night a chariot pass'd her
While on the ground she lay;
The daughters of her master
An evening visit pay;
Their tender hearts were sighing,
As negro wrongs were told,
While the white slave was dying,
Who gain'd their father's gold. |
This is true of another factory child, who just before died of
consumption, induced by protracted factory labour. With the last breath
upon her lips, she cried
out, "Father, is it time?" and so died.
The true ground of resentment is not that employers should take children
into workshops, for many workmen when they
become overseers, and derive a profit on child-labour, do the same thing;
it is that any workmen in England should be so base or so indigent as to
send
children into a workshop, and are not to be restrained save by an Act of
Parliament. If unable to protect their children it showed a humiliating
weakness,
and it was high time that the better-natured sought power by combination
to prevent it. This at least is
to their credit. These dreary facts of factory life recounted were told in
every household of workmen in the land, and no one can understand the
fervour and force with which industrial conspiracies were entered into,
who does not take them into account. Mr. Lucas Sargant, of Birmingham, has
stated that, "though his interest as employer might lead him to deprecate
trades unions and strikes, which have often caused him losses, he had
declared
in print his opinion that mechanics were wise to enter into such unions,
and occasionally to have resort to strikes."
A sense of right and sympathy always connected co-operators with the
industrial conspirators, allies, or advisers. It was on March 30, 1830,
that Mr. Pare
delivered his first public lecture in the Mechanics' Institution,
Manchester. He appeared as the corresponding secretary of the first
Birmingham
Co-operative Society. It was Birmingham who first sent co-operation
officially to Manchester. The editor of the United Trades Co-operative
Journal
wrote of Mr. Pare as being "A young man who impressed his audience by his
earnestness and wide information," but objected to his tone as to trades
unions. Mr. Pare did not speak in a directly hostile way of them, but
suggested the inability and uselessness of combining to uphold wages. Mr.
Pare had
caught Mr. Owen's indifferent opinion of everything save the "new system." But at that early period co-operators were intelligent partisans of trades
unions. The Manchester United Trades Co-operative Journal of May, 1830,
justified trades unions by the memorable saying of Sir Robert Peel in the
House
of Commons: "I wish the people would see their own interests, and take
the management of their affairs into their own hands." "Such is the
advice," said
the editor, which Mr.
Peel, the Secretary of State, has given the working classes. It is rare
indeed that public men, especially ministers of State,
offer such counsel, and it is still more rare for those to who the advice
is given to act upon it." It is a remarkable thing and a very
honourable
distinction that Sir Robert Peel should have conceived and given such
advice. Trades Unions and Co-operation are two of the matured answers to
it.
No advocate can influence others who is devoid of sympathy with them, and
is not scrupulous in doing justice to their best qualities. Co-operative
advocates have talked to unionists in as heartless a way as political
economists, and attempt to change their policy of action by holding it up
to ridicule as
financially foolish. Education in independence which men pay for
themselves, is a lesson those who learn it never forget, and is worth a
good deal.
The difference between the trade unionist and the co-operative way of
dealing with a strike is capable of historic illustration. In 1860 a
famous strike took
place in Colne, Lancashire. The weavers were out for fifty weeks and 4,000
looms were caused to be idle. Cogwheel, one of the weavers, put their case
thus. He said, "In Colne there
are 4,000 looms. In East Lancashire there are 90,000 looms. If the Colne
strike had not taken place the prices all over East Lancashire would have
been
reduced to the Colne standard, and therefore East Lancashire saved money
by contributing £20,000 to the Colne strike." Dr. Watts put the
co-operative view of the strike not less concisely thus: "If the Colne
people, instead of going on strike for fifty weeks, had kept at work and
lived on
half-wages, as they had to do during the strike, and had saved the other
half, and if the East Lancashire people had subscribed £20,000, as they
did,
towards keeping the Colne people on strike, the result at the end of fifty
weeks would have been £54,000 in hand, and at £15 a loom that money would
have set to work in perpetuity for the hands themselves 3,600 looms out of
the 4,000 in Colne! The selfsame effort which threw them into beggary
would have raised them into independence." [218]
The co-operator holds that the right thing to do is to prepare for
self-employment before striking. A trades-union strike is a contest of
starvation. It is
the siege of the fortress of capital with a view to its reduction by
famine, in which the besiegers are more likely to perish than the
besieged. It seems the
modest device of war when the belligerents who have the least strength
render themselves helpless in order to fight. The Comte de Paris happily
compares a strike and lock-out to a Japanese duel, in which each combatant
is under obligation to honour to put himself to death with his own hand.
Where trade unions limit the freedom of others in working its union,
action is tyranny. Lord Derby has told the case. "If what you are doing is
for your own
interest and for that of your fellow-workmen, in time those who now stand
aloof will
join you. In the meantime, 999 men out of 1,000 have no more right to
control the single dissentient than the one would have, were it in his
power, to
control them. There is hardly a despotism since the world began that has
not founded itself on the same plea that it would carry into effect more
surely than free citizens the recognised will of the majority. To refuse
to recognise the freedom of your neighbours is the first step towards
losing your
own." [219]
The hasty acts and imputations of ignorant workmen have often provoked
employers to high-handed injustice. Yet any one conversant with the
literature of
strikes must be well aware that the tone and language of men has been far
more moderate and deferential to masters than that of masters has been
fair
and considerate to the men. The United Trades Co-operative Journal of
Manchester relates that in 1830 the dressers and dyers of Manchester and
Salford
formed a Co-operative Society, the master spinners having a private trades
union of their own, had turned out simultaneously all their hands owing to
a
dispute about wages, and the master dyer had turned all his men out
because they wanted an hour for dinner and he would only give them half an
hour.
The men fearing all their comrades would be turned out by a general
conspiracy of their masters, resolved to begin work for themselves; but
as all the
premises suitable were in possession of masters, they were driven from
Ancoats to Pemberton before they could commence operations. The masters
being holders of all suitable property, or able to influence others who
held it, pursued their hands with malevolence.
Hundreds of strikes would have been averted, years of sullenness and
bitterness would have been avoided, had employers reconciled themselves to
the
admission that workmen were so far equals as to be entitled to conference
and explanation. Middle-class masters have been repellent. They would not
condescend to confer. They would receive no committee, they would admit no
delegates to their counting.
house. It was co-operators who first taught working people
how to respect themselves and to cease entreaty. They said "Do not discuss
with employers, dispense with them." None but co-operators could
give this proud counsel. [220] The great Newcastle-on-Tyne strike of 1866 had
been avoided, if employers concerned, who were known to have good feeling
towards men, had had ordinary condescension.
In Newcastle-on-Tyne the Daily Chronicle did more than any other newspaper
to prevent loss to employers, by a generous
and considerate advocacy of the claims of workmen. Where it could not
approve their claims, it conceded them free publicity of their case and
the
grounds on which they rested
it. Thus violence was averted which has occurred in other places where
workmen have been denied access to the press and treated with
contemptuous exclusion, or subjected to contemptuous criticism which they
were not allowed to answer.
Nor have the arguments oft employed by capitalists to restrain union
action been well chosen. Workmen were intimidated by being told that they
would
drive the trade of the country out of it. This consideration did cause
many of them to hesitate. In time they came to the conclusion that if they
could not get
living wages at home, they would be driven out of the country themselves,
and therefore, if they did "drive the work out of the country," there
might come
this advantage to them—that they would know where to find
it when they were driven out after it. Indeed, it was obvious that if
trade could not be kept in England except by workmen consenting to accept
starvation
wages, it could not be kept in England at all—for men on low wages would
emigrate sooner or later.
Few can be aware of what has been the experience of living men, or there
would be less severity in the judgment of those who labour. One bit of
real life is
more conclusive than many arguments. The president of the Rochdale
Co-operative Society in 1847, Mr. George Adcroft, told me to-day (October
3, 1877)
that when he worked in the pit, men got
coal without even a shirt on. They worked absolutely naked,
and their daughters worked by their side. This was seventy years ago. It
was the rule then for the men to be kept at work as long as there were
waggons at the pit mouth waiting to be filled. He and others were commonly
compelled to work sixteen hours a day; and from week's end to week's
end they never washed either hands or face. One Saturday night (he was
then a lad of fifteen) he and others had worked till twelve o'clock, still
there
were waggons at the pit mouth. They at last rebelled—refused to work any
later. The banksman went and told the employer, who came and waited till
they
were drawn up to the mouth and beat them with a stout whip as they came to
the surface. Despite the lashes they clambered up the chain cage, got hold
of the whip, and tried to kill the master. Negro slavery was not much
worse than that. Mr. Adcroft states that a man who had worked the long
hours he
describes would not earn more than 17s. or 19s. a week, and half of that
would be stopped for "tommy," on the truck system. Living unionists who
passed
through this state of things were not well trained for taking a
dispassionate and philosophical view of the relations of capital and
labour.
So long as the workman had enough to do to keep himself from the
poor-house, he could not be expected to think much about the pride of an
order which
had nothing to eat. The invention of the spinning jenny superseded the
small spinning-rooms by which so many lived, with some control over
their humble
fortunes. The jenny drove thousands into mills, where they were at the
mercy of capital and panics. Manufacturing by machinery put an end to most
of the
little workshops, and pride in handicraft which a man felt when the credit
or discredit of his work was connected with himself. Any reputation he was
enabled now to acquire in the mill passed to the credit of the firm who
employed him. He
became merely a machine, a little more trouble to manage than those
patented, and he sank, as an artificer, into little more consideration
than a man in a
large prison, who is known by his number instead of his name. He had no
longer a character to acquire or to lose. He was only "one of the hands";
his
health, his subsistence, or his recreation died out
also. The commencement of the trades unions of the modern kind was the
first evidence the workman gave of understanding
that he must do something for his own protection. That he blundered in the
method he adopted—that his efforts were marked by waste, coercion,
and retaliation, were small things compared with the great merit that he
struggled at all for some elevation. In late years he has had information
enough to
improve his methods. Yet no unionist leaders have arisen until the time of
Thomas Burt, M.P., who have comprehended, in the same degree as he, the
new possibilities of the day. Mechanics' institutions were established by
Dr. Birkbeck, Lord Brougham, Francis Place, and others, which languished
for
years. The class-rooms were more or less tenantless, the
teachers had few pupils. Had trades unionists understood what knowledge
would do for their children, had they taken note of the inferiority of
their
sons compared with the educated sons of middle-class masters under whom
they worked, they would have crowded the mechanics' institutions with
their
own sons. The higher manners, the preciser speech, the greater capacity,
the more disciplined mind, the tone of intellectual authority shown by
the sons of
their employers, should have taught them once and for ever that education
was the only equality in their power, and they should have insisted that
the sons
of every member of the union should be sent to the mechanics' institution. The leaders of the people who first devised mechanics' institutions
expected
that this would be done. The enemies of the people who disliked
"institutes," and distrusted them, and feared them, thought so too. Church
dignitaries, Conservative politicians, alarmed employers, and country
squires united to condemn the dangerous innovation of knowledge which
would
make the people discontented with "the position to which it had pleased
God to call them." All those fears were as foolish as they were wicked. The
workmen had, unhappily, not sufficient
sense of their own interests, and needed no restraining from using the
means of power placed at their disposal. They were without the
intelligence even to
see their opportunity.
The great trade guilds of London have mainly sunk into private dining
societies. [221] They do not represent the great traditions of industrial
pride. The modern
masters of guilds are without even the capacity to feel the inspiration
which made their forefathers the leaders of art in industry. To-day,
indeed, we hear
of the Turners' Company of London, awakening from their long, ignoble
sleep, offering prizes to young handicraftsmen for skill at the lathe;
and the
Baroness Burdett-Coutts, distinguished for discerning generosity, has
given the largest sum to be expended in this way. This is what trades
unions ought to have done long years ago, they should have given prizes
to the best
workmen in each trade. They could have had the money for asking. The first
persons in the State would have done them the honour of distributing their
prizes. The character of English workmen would have stood the highest in
the world in skill and in the self-respecting dignity of labour. No man
should
be admitted into a trade union unless he is a good workman, or willing to
be made one, and his being allowed to remain a member should be a
guarantee
to the public that he has skill which can be trusted. Now, a man being a
unionist is small guarantee to any one that he will not scamp his work or
do the least for the most he can get. Some of the first workmen of the
day, and men of character and good faith in work, are members of trades
unions,
but good skill and good faith are nowhere made the conditions of
membership. A trades union council are not leaders of art in industry;
they are, with a
few exceptions, mere connoisseurs in strikes. All a union does is to
strike against low wages; they never strike against doing bad work.
It
will be a great
thing for the reputation of industry in England when they do this. Now
they cover themselves with the excuse that their employers want bad and
cheap
things made. There is no moral difference in doing bad work
and picking the purchaser's pocket. A bungler is but a thief with a
circumbendibus in his method. Trades unions ought to resent the demand
that their
members should do bad work, as an affront upon their character as workmen.
Few well-devised strikes on this principle would raise wages as no union
has ever done yet, and, what is not less important, raise the whole
character of industry in England in a few years. This is one form of the
organisation of
labour wanted.
It is fair to own that trades unionists recognise the importance of their
efficiency as workmen. Several Congresses of trades have passed
resolutions
applauding the attainment of technical knowledge by workmen. The Society
of Arts at the Adelphi, London, which does so much for the advancement of
popular knowledge, issues yearly a programme of technological
examinations, in which mechanics of leading trades and men engaged in
agriculture are
offered an opportunity of proving their practical knowledge of the nature
of their employment. When they have done so certificates of three degrees
of
proficiency are awarded them, various prizes in money, and even
scholarships. Mr. George Howell for years transmitted the necessary
documents to
different trades to induce workmen to enter into these competitions. This,
however, is only approval of knowledge, not insistence upon it. There is
more
original artistic thought and pride among the artisan class than they are
credited with. The Matsys and Cellinis are not extinct. The famous
blacksmiths and
gold workers have merely had their genius turned in other directions by
science. The old artists who worked for fame in their obscure chambers are
succeeded by men who expend genius and devotion in devising wondrous
machinery. They are Pygmalions of invention who impart to inanimate metal
the
miraculous action of living intelligence. They think in poverty—they die
neglected, and their splendid ingenuity enriches the nation. The acclaim
of their
genius never reaches the dull, cold ear of death. In later generations the
tardy monumental bust is erected over their forgotten graves. The Patent
Office is
the record of their fine patience and
unrequited skill. Mr. George Wallis has discerningly pointed out that the
originality of the artisan class is expressed in machinery in these days. Living unnoted men see hidden
things in mechanics which would have made Archimedes famous.
Some people are manifestly born before their time; some are born after—a
very long while after—and in any well-regulated system ought to be put
back
again. There are others apparently born for no time in particular; they
are neither offensive nor useful, but chiefly in the way of other people;
while there are
others who belong to the age and know it, who comprehend very well the
opportunities of the hour, who employ them and mean to put them to
account.
The alliance between co-operators and trade unionists has been of long
standing. On the 21st of April, 1834, Mr. Owen headed the great procession
to
Lord Melbourne to ask the release of the Dorchester labourers. The
unionists assembled in Copenhagen Fields. Lord Melbourne agreed to receive
a
limited deputation of leaders at Downing Street. On the list of names
handed in to him Mr. Owen's name was not included, it being probably
thought that
Mr. Owen being known to Lord Melbourne would be admitted. His lordship,
preferring to see the men alone, refused to see any one not on the list he
had
assented to. Thus the interview took place without the assistance of their
most important advocate.
During the early period of the co-operative movement the Socialists and
Unionists might be heard from the same platform advocating their
respective
principles. [222] At Salford the society opened a subscription to support a
strike. [223] In London Mr. Owen was elected the Grand Master of a lodge, and
he permitted the trade societies to use his lecture hall. [224] The
Crisis added to
its title that of National Co-operative Trades Union and Equitable
Exchange
Gazette. Mr. Owen specially charged himself to effect the release of the
Dorchester convicts, but the demonstration which took place on the
occasion is
said to have exercised an unfortunate influence by increasing the severity
of the Government. [225] But that was not Mr. Owen's fault. It rested with
those who devised a demonstration which could only increase the alarm
which led to the severity the procession ought to stop. Mr. Owen must have
depended on others influence than that of the streets to effect the
release of the men.
Trades unions are simply fighting powers on behalf of labour, just as
employers' unions are fighting powers on
behalf of capital. Masters' unions do not concern themselves with the
improvement of manufactures, with excellence of
material, or equitable charges to the public. So far as their action
appears they consult only the preservation of profits. On the other hand,
workmen's
unions, as such, mainly charge themselves with the protection or increase
of wages. They can issue advice to workmen to refuse, as far as possible,
to
work except for employers where a partnership of industry exists. It is
quite as legitimate for them to strike against employers who refuse this,
as to strike
against those who refuse
increase of wages. Indeed, strikes for partnerships would he fairer than
strikes for wages, because in partnerships the profits must be earned
before they
can be had; whereas in strikes for wages the employer is simply plundered
if he is forced to yield where he cannot really afford it, just as the
public are
plundered when unions of capitalists, or merchants, combine to raise at
will the price of commodities which the public must have.
Even at Co-operative Congresses now, we hear from leaders who are making
profits in joint-stock companies, vigorous arguments against conceding to
workmen a share of profits. They say, just as competitive employers have
always said, capital takes all the risks and the workman has his share of
the
profits in his wages. Asking for what they are pleased to denominate a
"bonus" on labour, they treat the demand as a gift, and if it is granted
they describe it
as proceeding from the "benevolence" of the employer. It is time this
chatter of charity on the part of capitalists was ended. A co-operative
store or a
co-operative workshop, where the profits belong to the producers, is a
mutual arrangement. But competition is not an arrangement; it is war. The
interests
of capital and labour are in conflict; and the demands for participation
in profits after capital, management,
and expenses have been paid, is no hostile act. Capital as a rule gives
the least it can, and labour as a rule exacts the most
it can. In Co-operation mutual arrangement renders the equitable divisions
of profit a right, and "bonus" and "benevolence" pernicious and offensive
terms.
When at the Amsterdam Exhibition some years ago I went one day, at the
invitation of Baron Mackay (since Lord Reay), to see the great works of
the new
canal out in the Zuyder Lee. Far away on the sands 'mid the North Sea I
found what I took to be a Dutch chapel. Its pretty overhanging roofs and
quaint
desks and seats within, all out there, surprised
me. On asking what it was, I was told it was the schoolhouse for the
education of the children of the Dutch workmen, employed in cutting and
building
the mighty canal
through plains of sand lying out in the North Sea. "Why do you erect a
school-house out here?" I inquired of the chief
contractor, who was a Scot. "You do nothing of the kind
in your own country. Contractors do nothing of the kind in
England." "Oh," was the reply, "it is a convenience for the workmen's
families." "Yes, I understand all that," I answered, "but what sets you
upon consulting
their convenience in Holland when you never think of it elsewhere?" "Well, the truth is," he at last admitted, "that the Dutch workmen having
good secular
schools in every town where their children can be educated, and knowing
the advantages of it, having profited themselves when young by it, will
not work
for any one who does not provide schools where their
families can be trained." This shows what intelligent workmen can do who
have the sense to understand their own interests, and this is what English
workmen might do with respect to education and participation of profits,
if they had as much wit and determination as the drowsy, dreaming,
much smoking, but clear-minded, resolute Dutch.
Adjoining the school-house was a large co-operative store, exactly on the
plan of the one first devised by Robert Owen at Lanark. It consisted of a
large
wood building containing large stores of provisions, lodged there by the
contractors and put in charge of a storekeeper, who sold them at cost
price
less his wages as salesman. This was a further economy for the men; it
made their wages go farther, and was an additional source of contentment
to
them, costing the employers nothing save forethought and good feeling. This was the
only co-operative store I ever found on the ocean; it lay in mid-seas.
Though Co-operation is an English movement, its history takes us a good
deal over the world—for as we have said elsewhere—Co-operative devices
of
industry have appeared in other countries during two centuries past. Groups of men acting together for their own advantage are historic
features of many
lands; and countless undertakings, not bearing the co-operative name,
illustrate the inspiration of the spirit and power of concert.
"The Conflicts of Labour and Capital—a History and Review of Trades
Unions," by George Howell, may be mentioned as the ablest book yet
produced by
an English Trade Unionist leader, as the work of Nadaud is the best
produced by a French workman. In point of weight of authority and
exhaustive
treatment Mr. W. T. Thornton's volume on "Labour" stands next to the
writings of Mr. J. S. Mill. The philosophy and practice of Unionism and
Cooperation
are dealt with by Mr. Thornton with a completeness and impartiality not
elsewhere to be found.
CHAPTER XXX.
CO-OPERATIVE FAILURES
"If thou wishest to be wise,
Keep these lines before thine eyes;
If thou speakest—how beware!
Of whom, to whom, and when and where."
BYRON. |
WHERE the principle of Industrial Partnership is
adopted by workmen it is sometimes superseded rather than abandoned. Outsiders come in as
shareholders, and not caring for Co-operation, they seize the society as
soon as they are able, outvote the co-operative members, and convert it
into a
joint stock business, which they believe to be more immediately profitable
to them. This was the way the Mitchell Hey Society at Rochdale fell. Though
these instances are but perversions, the business is still conducted by
working men, which implies that a larger number of working men are
acquiring the
skill of masters. This is a progress after its kind, though wanting in the
principle of equity and equality, which Co-operation aims to introduce
among
workmen. There have been no co-operative failures, save from errors into
which commercial men of greater experience occasionally fall. Dr. John
Watts
has given an account of the failure of the
Queenwood community. As he was one of those concerned
in it, his evidence has weight. He says "the failure of the Hampshire
community was attributable, amongst other causes, firstly, to the
extravagant price
paid for very poor land; secondly, to the large amount of capital sunk in
buildings
which were not profitably occupied; and, thirdly, to the attempt to
convert skilled artisans, used to good wages, into agriculturists upon bad
land; and to satisfy them with agricultural labourers' fare, and no money
wages." [226]
The tone of the press is greatly changed toward the failures of working
men in their manufacturing enterprises. In days of the limited and dear
press, newspapers mostly represented the interests of masters; when a
working-class enterprise failed the matter was mentioned with contemptuous
derision, and was treated as a warning to men not to exhibit the
presumption that they could be masters. When a failure occurs to working
men now, it is thought to be a misfortune that they are not able to better
their condition by industrial enterprise. If their failure has arisen
through an unforeseen rise in prices, which made their contracts
unprofitable, or through the bankruptcy of customers owing them money
whose solvency they had no reason to doubt when they took their orders, [227]
or if the losses of the men have arisen from unexpected decay of trade,
the same allowance is made now in the judgment of their failure as is made
in the case of other manufacturers who conduct business on competitive
principles.
When the Ouseburn Engine Works failed the Eastern Daily Press remarked
that "Mr. Holyoake would have to chronicle that in his History," which he
certainly intended to do; but in justice to the Eastern Press I record
that that failure was judged in that journal upon its merits. It was not,
as formerly would have been the case, set down as a failure of the
co-operative principle, but regarded as arising from errors in business
management, and the outside causes of the loss were fairly taken into
account. The main source of failure was a series of contracts made by an
agent (£30,000 under their values), which no manager who understood his
business would have permitted.
The co-operators are the most open creatures who ever entered into
business. So far from concealing a failure, they proclaim it too loudly,
their desire being that all may take note what to avoid in the future. When the Ouseburn Engine Works had lost the £30,000 through Dr. Rutherford
making suspicious contracts, the fact was publicly proclaimed. He was not
dismissed, nor did he resign, so that the co-operators were the pity of
all the Tyneside for remaining under the management which had brought the
great disaster upon them. Incapacity is of the nature of a crime when it
meddles with the fortune of a struggling cause, or does not take itself
away when its incompetence is plainly perilous. The Ouseburn workmen
behaved admirably. When they were informed that false contracts had been taken,
involving the enormous loss cited, it was open to them to avenge
themselves by executing the work badly; but they honestly resolved to
execute it to the best of their ability notwithstanding, and they did so;
and no engine works on the Tyneside ever won higher credit for honest and
perfect workmanship. They got through their great and unjustifiable
losses. It was by failure of subsequent creditors that the concern fell
into liquidation.
People who hear now and then of the failure of co-operative engine works
or mines imagine they forbode the end of that system and do not take into
account that other persons who are not workmen, and who are experienced in
business, fail also. At the time of the Ouseburn difficulty the Daily
Chronicle, at Newcastle-on-Tyne, published a list of the failures which
had occurred in Cleveland in the course of twelve months, with the amount
of the liability in five cases. The following is the list :—
Sivert Hjerlid, ironfounder, Middlesbrough.
North Yorkshire Iron Co., Limited.
W. A. Stevenson, iron merchant.
Eston Grange Iron Co., Eston.
Thomas Richardson & Sons.
Nicholas Raine, South Hylton Ironworks.
R. Jaques, Richmond Ironworks, Stockton.
J. H. Garbutt, coalowner, Darlington.
E. Watteau, bolt and nut manufacturer, Middlesbrough.
Erimus Iron Company, Middlesbrough.
F. Ireland, iron merchant, Middlesbrough.
Middlesbrough Cut Nail Works.
Stockton Rail Mill Co., Stockton.
The Britannia Iron Company, Middlesbrough.
Ross, Willis & Co., Middlesbrough.
Thos. Vaughan & Co., Middlesbrough.
J. B. Walker, shipowner, Middlesbrough.
Swan, Coates & Co., Middlesbrough.
Raylton, Dixon & Co., shipbuilders, Middlesbrough.
Thos. Charlton & Co., coal and ironstone mine owners, Middlesbrough.
South Cleveland Iron Co., Limited.
The Lackenby Iron Co., Middlesbrough.
R. H. Charlton, Stranton Ironworks, Hartlepool.
Messrs. Thomas & Co., ironfounders, Middlesbrough.
J. W. Thomas, Acklam Refinery.
West Hartlepool Iron Co., Limited. |
|
Liabilities. |
Thos.
Vaughan & Co. ... ... ... ... |
£1,200,000 |
Swan,
Coates & Co. ... ... ... ... ... |
230,000 |
Lackenby
Iron Co. ... ... ... ... ... |
200,000 |
R. Dixon &
Co. ... ... ... ...
... |
175,000 |
Messrs.
Charlton ... ... ... ... ... |
__270,000 |
|
£2,125,000 |
Only one of these firms was expected to pay more than 5s, in the pound.
Some years ago the Wholesale Society of Glasgow lost £10,000 by an
investment made without their formal authority. There was, however, no
doubt that the investment, though irregular, was made in good faith, and
had it turned out fortunate it had been applauded. The Society remembered
this, and quietly provided for the loss, and took precautions that the
same thing should not occur again. Not long ago the Halifax Society lost
£60,000 by injudicious investment in Foreign Securities. The members
behaved like men of business. They knew that had the large profits they
calculated upon accrued, they would have thought their directors "smart
fellows." They did not break up their society as a few wild members,
stimulated by shopkeepers, proposed; and as their predecessors did a
generation earlier, on the loss of less then 160th part of that sum. They
simply arranged to repair the loss from future profits, and made a note to
invest more prudently in future. Working men who have acquired this kind
of good sense will very rarely stumble into failure.
If a series of failures disproved a principle, what must be said of the
failures of competition, where twenty men fail for one who succeeds? Had
any one invented competition it would have been hooted out of the world
long ago as an infernal contrivance of spite and greed. To use a phrase
made picturesque by Mr. Henley in the House of Commons, competition is an
"ugly rush "—an ugly rush after bones,
which everybody is equally ambitious to pick. As to failure, what are the
failures of banking? Let those hideous, criminal, calamitous failures be
catalogued, and banking must be pronounced unsound in principle. Co-operation, in its most unfortunate days,
will bear comparison with banking.
Messrs. Fox, Head & Co., of Middlesbrough, proposed, with fair intentions,
a partnership of industry with their men; but stipulated that the men
should give up their trades unions and sign a contract to that effect. The
company on their
part agreed to withdraw from the masters' union. They were
at liberty to please themselves in this matter. But the condition they
exacted from the men was a degrading condition. What was it to them to
what purposes the men put their earnings so long as they fulfilled their
contract with them? The proceeding of this company was an abuse of
industrial
partnership, and calculated to bring it into disrepute. It had been far
better had they never touched the question.
The Messrs. Briggs, of the Whitwood Collieries, brought their scheme to an
end in a similar spirit. Their partnership with their men brought them
great gain while it lasted. Some years several thousands of pounds were
divided among their workmen, being merely the half-profits made by the
increased exertion and care of the men, apart from the exceptional profits
of the years when the price of coal rose greatly. But the total made in
the way of profit while the partnership lasted has never been declared. [228]
The Messrs. Briggs appear to have taken advantage of their men attending a
certain trades union meeting, which they had forbidden them to attend, to
exclude them from the partnership, and even to withhold from some the
money they had earned in the partnership. This dictation to their men in
matters outside their duties to the company, was a disastrous lesson to
set the
men. It has been inferred that the company found strikes less
expensive than fulfilling an honourable partnership. They may have
terminated it because it was more troublesome to them than their interest
in the welfare of their men induced them to take. They have given no
satisfactory explanation of the facts, financial or otherwise, involved in
the case. The failure, so far as it is known, has not been on the part of
the men, but on the part of their employers.
When the Messrs. Briggs first proposed to adopt some plan of co-operative
partnership in their collieries, I received from them several letters
explanatory of their objects, and of the difficulties which presented
themselves. With a view to promote their wise intention, to diminish
obstacles which the prejudices of trades unionists might entertain towards
the project, and to support the Messrs. Briggs in their views, to justify
them in the eyes of other employers, and to increase their public credit
for taking a lead in so useful and honourable a design, I solicited
opinions of the project from Mr. John Stuart Mill, Professor Fawcett,
Louis Blanc, and others, to whom I explained the possible industrial
advantages of it. The letters I received were published, and the words of
honour spoken of these employers by such friends of equitable industry
were repeated in their praise. In any way I could I was glad to strengthen
their hands; but the letters I received at that time from the Messrs.
Briggs did not make me very sanguine that they would carry their plan
through, or persevere in it from conviction of its public advantage. They
manifestly
inherited a distrust of workmen. They imputed venality and self-interest
to leading unionists who advised their men. They thought too much of
disparaging and destroying trade unions. They spoke too much of the
proposed participation of profits as a "bonus" to the men, as though it
were a largess or gracious gift to the workmen arising from their
employers' goodness of disposition and depending for its continuance upon
the good behaviour of their hands. Their plan was complex, there were too
many conditions, and even the conditions were conditional. It would,
however, be unfair to make much of these peculiarities. The project was
new in their business. They could not foresee to what administrative
inconvenience it might lead. Conflicting claims, interest, and prejudices
are always called into play when any new plan is adopted among the working
class more or less uninformed, or unfamiliar with it. These were real
difficulties which might well render the best-disposed employers uncertain
as to the measures to which they would commit themselves. Besides, the
Messrs. Briggs
were not themselves co-operators. The principle and definite
line of thought which Co-operation implies must have been strange to them. It therefore remains a credit to them that they entertained the idea of
establishing co-operative relations in their works, and actually attempted
it. It would be scant encouragement to other employers to try the same
thing if those who do try it, and do not succeed in carrying it forward,
or turn back discouraged, were to be treated with less consideration than
those who never made any attempt of the kind. What Mr. J. S. Mill thought
of their attempt he stated very strongly in his letter to me from Saint Veran, Avignon (Nov. 21, 1864). "The Messrs. Briggs have done themselves
great honour in being the originators in England of one of the two modes
in Co-operation which are probably destined to divide the field of
employment between them. The importance of what they are doing is the
greater, as its success would make it almost impossible hereafter for any
recreant co-operative societies to go back to the old plan of paying only
fixed wages when even private capitalists give it up." Unfortunately they
have returned to fixed wages and given comfort thereby to others besides
"recreant co-operative societies."
The failures of co-operative stores have been infrequent. Their success as
a rule is so overwhelming that any failures have been due to common
neglect of well-defined precautions which experience has established. Mr.
J. C. Farn has relevantly pointed out that:
"the art of organisation was
in its infancy thirty years ago; now (1878), if it is incomplete in
practice, it arises from neglect, and not for want of models. Popular
intolerance in days gone by was a hundred times more powerful than it is
now. Without tolerance, societies cannot permanently succeed. The
co-operative ship of thirty years since had to sail over the sea of
difficulty without chart or compass. Now the rocks are known and marked
dangerous, none but unskilful or neglectful pilots need allow the ship to
strike upon them. Finally, with more members, more money, more experience,
more support, more confidence, more tolerance, and sounder views, there is
no reason to believe that the disasters of former times will be repeated."
One source of distrust to which co-operative enterprises are subject
arises in the enthusiasm in which they are often commenced. The projectors
of a new company, conscious of the
purity of their own intentions, behave just as knaves do, when they set
floating a fraudulent scheme. They deprecate all inquiry into it, and
regard any one who points out objections or difficulties to be
encountered, as a disagreeable person who wants to damp the enthusiasm of
others, and destroy the prospects of a company which he does not intend to
help. The enthusiastic promoters are so strong in the honesty of their
intentions, that they imagine their wisdom to be as obvious as their
integrity, and regard doubts of their success as imputations upon
themselves; they do not perceive that just objects, and noble aims,
though necessary to the success of an unusual enterprise, do not
necessarily make it successful. There must be fair business prospects and
fair business sense in addition, in
order that great interest may be taken in any project. There must be
confidence in the capacity as well as the honour of those who promote it;
and confidence depends upon the knowledge of the persons and purposes of
those with whom it is proposed to work; and it is wisdom in the promoters
of any new company to furnish this information, without waiting to be
asked for it. It is good policy to solicit all the objections that can be
made at the outset of a concern, so that they may not come when it is too
late to profit by them. The objector is a very valuable person, if
enthusiasts knew how to profit by him. Enthusiasm, desire of personal
distinction, or hope of profit, is apt to blind the understanding, and the
wise, objector (if he can be found) is the occulist who opens the eyes of
the company, and enables the members to see what the facts of the case
really are. It matters not how strong or peculiar the points urged in
opposition may be, the general soundness of a sound scheme can always be
shown, and shown to far greater advantage when the objector has given his
evidence against it in open court, than it could before he was heard. If
the soundness of the project cannot, then, be made clear, it is better for
all concerned that the difficulty should be apparent. Objections may be
disallowed, or overruled, but they should be heard, and considered as far
as their relevance seems to warrant. When this is done, the shareholders
find themselves well advised and candidly informed, and they go into the
undertaking with their eyes open; and if it does not answer they
have nobody to reproach but themselves. They feel none of the bitterness
of men who have been misled by others, and they even feel respect for
those who afforded them so fair an opportunity of knowing the truth; and
the failure involves no loss of self-respect to any one, since a fair
measure of prudence had marked the proceedings. But if critics, suggestors,
or objectors, who do the society the service of volunteering advice upon
its affairs, are put down as offensive or suspicious persons, the interest
of members is foolishly jeopardised. If the promoters of a doubtful or
dishonest company succeed in obtaining the money of the shareholders,
everybody can see that it is as criminal a thing as though that money had
been taken by an act of burglary, and is more irritating to those who lose
by it, because insidious professions have made them parties to their own
loss. The wrong done by honest, earnest projectors of schemes is not less
serious in its results because unintended. But their honest intentions do
not absolve them from criminality, if they have incurred risks without the
fullest inquiry possible into them, and without communicating the results
of that inquiry to all whom they invited to share those risks with them. Of course there are projects continually started where the profits depend
upon celerity and secrecy of action. In these cases it is obvious that to
solicit objections from outsiders would betray the purpose. In such
concerns only a few persons are ever engaged, and they know perfectly what
they are doing, and do not go about complaining if their money is lost. It
is public companies where shareholders are sought among persons of large
and small means alike, and who invest money and trust in the honour and
capacity of the directors of the company, that a scrupulous and complete
information should be furnished, as a matter of fair precaution and good
faith. It should be a matter of pride in co-operators that no failure
should take place among them. Their aim should be to acquire the
reputation not only for honesty, but for soundness of judgment, and
sureness of procedure. In the days of Harry Clasper and Robert Chambers it
was known that when Newcastle oarsmen rowed a match upon any river, they
would win if they could—they were never to be bought. They contested for
the honour of the Tyneside; and co-operators should always be known as
contesting for the honour of Co-operation.
A frequent source of failure arises from a cause which involves no
imputation upon the honesty of those concerned that is, "commencing a
project with too little capital." Though this implies merely want of
judgment, the effect of failure is the same upon the outside public, who
never trouble to notice why a thing fails. The failure itself is enough
for them, and the cause with which it is connected is damaged in their
eyes. "Insufficiency of capital" is so vague a cause, and is so often used
as an excuse for graver errors, that nobody accepts it for much. It
depends upon whether the scale of expenditure had been prudent and
cautious from the beginning, whether the capital is really too small. Deficiency may be produced by imprudent and disproportionate expenditure. Deficiency of capital is of course a distinct and determinable cause of
failure, and should be guarded against like any other. It often arises
through enthusiasm which impels
premature action. A meeting is called to consider whether a
new scheme can be undertaken. Good and approving plaudits
will soon be heard, if the proposal be popular. Some generous person is
inspired by the hearty applause to make a liberal offer of support. He
probably mistakes the enthusiasm for intelligent, well-considered purpose. Professor Tyndall has proved
that heat is a mode of motion. Prof. Crooks has proved that light is a
source of movement, and delicate machines have been contrived for
estimating these forces. But no one has invented a machine which will
denote the quality of applause; some men applaud because they are
impulsive, some because they approve of the proposal, some because they
intend to help it—when it succeeds; but the greater part applaud because
they think somebody else is going to aid it; and it frequently comes to
pass that experiments are commenced under the contagion of chequeless
enthusiasm, which only considerable capital can carry out. There are
always sanguine and dangerous people, who think a right thing will get
support if it is once begun. But wise promoters should never permit action
to be taken till reasonable means of carrying it out are secured.
A man who has had experience in popular movements becomes a connoisseur in
enthusiasm, and is disposed to analyse it before he counts upon it as an
element of action. When Mr, Forster was proposing his 25th clause to the
Education
Act in the House of Commons he stretched out his arm before the
Opposition, and informed them he had Puritan blood in his veins. I begged
a member who happened to be in the Speaker's gallery at the time to go
down and ask
Mr. Forster to put a drop of that blood into his Bill. The Nonconformists
said "the blood would do no good, it was of
a degenerate quality." I asked Professor Huxley whether he could analyse
one of the globules that we might know whether the quality was pure. This
is what has to be done with popular enthusiasm, its blood must be tested
before it can be trusted. If this were oftener done failures of
co-operative enterprise, though small in number now, would be fewer still.
A considerable number of manufacturing and productive societies have been
formed which have included the principle of partnership with labour, which
have scarcely gone beyond the publication of rules. In some instances
capital has not been subscribed sufficient to enable the undertaking to be
commenced, or not sufficient to carry on business long enough for
success. In other cases the accession of new shareholders who joined for
profit mainly, not caring about improving the general relations of labour
to capital, have, when profits were low, voted against sharing them with
workmen. Sometimes they have done this because the profits were great, and
they became covetous of obtaining all for themselves. Such shareholders
being shrewd, and not caring for the advancement of workmen, have
calculated that the cost of strikes was less than the loss, through
conceding a share of profit to the men, have deliberately elected to take
the risk of strikes, and rescinded the rule of participation. In a new
business, depending for prosperity upon sales in the market, greater
capital often becomes necessary than was at first calculated upon; and
being exigent it becomes necessary to take from any subscribers of shares
who may offer, without inquiry as to whether they are co-operators or not. In the early days of Co-operation every society instituted a propagandist
department, for winning co-operators to join them, or of educating them
afterwards. Where this is not done, and shareholders are received without
precaution, principle is left at the mercy of new members, and often
drifts and disappears. In this way principle was cancelled very early in
the Rochdale Co-operative Manufacturing Society of Mitchell Hey. In this
way it was attempted to be destroyed in the Hebden Bridge Fustian
Co-operative Society, but happily resisted successfully by the loyalty of
a sufficient number of the members. The "Fustian" had not got into their
brains.
It is no matter of discouragement that even co-operators turn back after
proceeding for awhile along the new path. Many make their way badly along
an unaccustomed road, and naturally return again to the old trodden path
with which they
are familiar. All men must live somehow, and industrial or commercial
fighting is the only general way in which men have been able to sustain
themselves. Until adventurous pioneers show how the needs of life can be
better commanded, the timid, or rapacious, impatient, or distrustful will
be uncertain adherents.
CHAPTER XXXI.
AMERICAN SOCIETIES
As wine and oil are imported to us from
abroad, so must ripe understanding and many civil virtues be imported into
our minds from foreign writings: we shall else miscarry still, and come
short in the attempts of any great enterprise.—MILTON'S
Hist. of Brit., Book iii.
THE English students of co-operative science found
hospitality for their ideas in America when they found none in England. No
English journal of the importance and character of the New York Tribune,
founded by Horace Greeley, ever accorded the attention to it, the hearing
to it, or the vindication of it which he accorded there. He himself
promoted Co-operation and wrote upon it with that practical clearness by
which he was distinguished. As a journalist he aided whoever assisted by
thought and art the improvement of social life. From sentiments of public
admiration, not less than from the regard inspired by his personal
friendship, I inscribed to him my "History of Co-operation in Halifax." While schemes of social life have originated with philosophers and
theorists, Co-operation has been generated by the pressure of competition
in over-populated cities.
As to moral scepticism in America, there is no more of it than there is in
England, while there are certainly more people in America than in England
who
sacrifice time, money, and, what is more, personal repute, to try and
carry out social schemes of life which can never benefit themselves.
America owes its chief co-operative inspiration to English Socialist
emigrants. Its communities have been mainly originated by European
world-makers.
The late Mr. Bellamy Hoare, of New York, possessed the most authentic
information as to the earliest efforts to establish Co-operation there. But the
narratives he is said to have left have not yet been obtained.
A former member of the Socialist Branch 16, Hall of Science, London, Mr.
B. J. Timms, was concerned in the affairs of the Sylvania Phalanx and the
Co-operative Bakery of the City of New York, which are deemed the original
societies of this kind there. The date of their operations cannot be at
present
determined, as Mr. Timms so little foresaw that any persons might one day
be curious about them, that he sold as wastepaper the printed and
manuscript documents relating to them. These projects were succeeded by
what was known as the organisation of Morrisania, devised to purchase land
for a village. The few actual Socialists in the society could not induce
the majority to unite further than in buying the land collectively; so
that the only
co-operative feature in the scheme was the joint effort to obtain land
without loss by the competition of each making a separate purchase, and
every one
searching the original title. Mr. Timms reports that subsequently they attempted
to apply the principle of Co-operation to colonise public lands, but after
spending
5,000 dollars of other people's
money, that scheme failed. These facts show how in America (as used to be
the case in England) the one story of Co-operation is that it is always
failing. Still the efforts go on, as though there were some industrial
destiny in Co-operation. So long as many who have failed live, very few
workers
around them have the courage to approach the question; but no sooner do
those who have failed die, or the memory of their disaster fades, than
fresh
pioneers resume the old work—and succeed. In other cases the fresh
adventurers are fortunate enough to meet with some old and brave
campaigners
who, though they lost their money, never lost their faith, and who never
cease to proclaim that others may win though they were
beaten. In America many were willing to see it run, but few
ran with it. Co-operative correspondence from other countries shows that
the co-operator abroad is much like the Irishman—a very different person from what he is at home. In Ireland he is sluggish
and despondent; in America he is active and enterprising. In like manner
the
discouraged co-operator at home stoutly predicts and stoutly promotes
co-operative success abroad, and counts those ignorant who do not
understand the principle, and those of an inferior order of mind who do
not believe in it.
The Morrisania, the First Co-operative Village, as it was called, is now a
large town. Dr. Hollick, writing in New York, says: "Co-operative
affairs, as far as
I can see, went on this plan: some man of money was elected treasurer. No
money was paid to him, and as long as he honoured all drafts made on him
the thing prospered; but when he discontinued this obliging arrangement
the thing 'bust up.' Horace Greeley was treasurer to two or three
schemes, and his official duty consisted in paying the expenses."
One of the few co-operative societies of America,
English in its vicissitudes, un-English in its mode of working, is one at
New Bedford, Fall River. Provisions being high, and other things, as
in England, being costly, a few persons who had been connected with
co-operative societies in this country, bethought themselves of setting up
one there. Certain dressers clubbed their money, bought goods at
wholesale prices, and at first divided them at their private houses.
Their business soon grew, and they had to open a store. Then the
grocers of Fall River—storedealers, as they are called
out there—did as we have found them do in England, went in a body to the
wholesale traders, telling them that if they supplied the co-operators
they, the storedealers, would no longer buy of them. The dressers were consequently
rejected as customers, and they went to Providence, a town fourteen miles
away, and tried to buy there. The storekeepers at Fall River attempted to
terrify the wholesale traders of Providence; but intimidation in business
is not so
easy in America as in England. Some of the Providence traders were men of
business, and told the storekeepers of Fall River "to go home and
mind their own business; for so far as they were concerned they should
sell to whomsoever they pleased." The dressers were customers worth
having,
and Providence dealers sold to them, and the dressers obtained goods and
triumphed. Shortly the spinners, weavers, and other trades joined the
dressers, until twenty-one trades were united, having sixty members each,
and the co-operative store soon did a business to the amount of 2,500
dollars
a month. This evidence of success brought the intimidated Fall River
dealers to
their senses, and then they came and offered to supply the co-operators
whom they had rejected, and so Co-operation conquered in Fall River. The
plan
of working the society there, which is not common in English experience,
is this: a committee manage its affairs at a cost of 4 per cent. for
rent,
buying, and selling. On the second Tuesday in each month they receive
orders, which are copied out on to a large sheet
with printed and descriptive headings. From the 12th to the
13th they receive money which covers all the orders. Then their buyer goes
to the wholesale traders (who now raise no objection to his visits); to
them he gives his orders, paying cash therewith, and on the four following
evenings men appointed for the purpose serve out the purchases to the
accredited applicants. The society buys nothing save what is ordered—orders nothing but
what is paid for—it keeps no stock—has no bad debts—no paid
storekeepers—and having no provisions on hand to keep, a small place is
sufficient for its business, and that is open only four or five nights in
the month. [229]
From Lombard Ville Stark Co. I learn, on the testimony of one who has been
for thirty-five years a communist, that the fortunes of industry are
hampered
by combinations and monopolist "rings" out there. There seems to be no
place where these cobras of competition do not crawl around the resources
of
the poor.
At the Glasgow Congress (1876) greetings were received from the Grangers
of America. Mr. J. W. A. Wright, who represented them, gave me this
extract from the published
proceedings of those bodies: "That, having examined the plan of the
co-operative societies of Great Britain, popularly known as the Rochdale
plan, and
the history of the humble beginning, the most remarkable success, and
present grand proportions of business enterprises begun and conducted
under
this plan, we heartily recommend it to the careful consideration of our
State and Subordinate Granges, and to the members of our order, and advise
such
action on the part of the executive committee of the several States as may
be necessary to the organisation and operation of such co-operative
associations within our order."
It appears that we were once nearer than we ever shall be again to having
a history of American communities. We learn from what Mr. Noyes relates,
that
a Scotch printer and a disciple of Mr. Owen, who had settled in New York,
devoted himself between 1840 and 1854, to personally collecting materials
for
the history of the communities in the United States, social and
co-operative, their origin, principles, progress, or decline and causes of
failure. Little
is known of him save that he was a person of small stature, black hair,
sharp eyes, and a good
natured face. In any circular to the societies he signed himself
"A. J. Macdonald." He wisely went himself to the sites of
the various communities. He collected particulars of sixty-nine associative
schemes, and portraits and sketches of founders and places; but
unfortunately died of cholera in New York about 1854, before he had time
to state in a book the results of his investigations. Mr. Jacobi was
another
investigator who spent several years visiting the chief communities, but
his
journeyings also are barren for the purposes of history. Mr. Jacobi knew
the state of these establishments in 1858.
Some business-like account of all the known social schemes which the
hospitable soil of the United States has received or nurtured, would be
curious.
Under this impression I took up Mr. Noyes' "History of American
Socialisms" with interest,
and laid it down without any. Mr. Noyes is an Oneidaite merely, and has no
appreciation for forms of social life, except as they approximate to that
peculiar creation of connubial
novelties known as Oneidaism. It is allowable that he should applaud his
own theory, but not that he should disparage every other. Lately there
has appeared a new book on "American
Communities," by William Alfred Hines. It is Oneidan in tone, but written
with great freshness and vigour. It is next to Nordhoff's work in force
and
interest.
Mrs. Ann Stanley, known to the public as "Ann Lee," proved a most
successful community-maker. She was practically the foundress of the
Shakers of
1774. Eighteen societies exist at this day (1878). There is a small
compendium of Shaker principles, and a Life of Ann Lee, by F. W. Evans,
published
by Auchampaugh Brothers, of New Lebanon. The brevity of the book is a
recommendation, for it is as much as most persons will be able to bear.
This body of communists
are the best known and the most frequently referred to, because they have
made communism a by-word in the world by fanaticism and eccentricity. Mr.
Evans's book is worth consulting, that the Shakers may be judged in the
fairest way by their own
professions. Ann Stanley, the foundress or chief prophetess of the order,
was a Mrs. Abraham Stanley, but her people never called her by her
husband's name. She appears to have had strange and disagreeable
conversations with her mother on
marriage previous to her own. However, her reasons for joining the Shaker
Society were creditable to her, as she considered them distinguished
for the clearness and swiftness of their testimony against sin—a very
great merit if they knew what sin was; and if the Shakers of 1878 retain
the
characteristic which Mrs. Stanley believed the first Shakers to possess,
they would be very useful, could they be diffused over Europe, where
people of that quality are very much needed. "Mother Ann," as Mrs.
Stanley came to be called, held that it could not be wrong to imitate
Jesus the
wifeless.
Shaker is an uncomfortable name, and gives most persons the idea of a
lean, shivering enthusiast, but their conduct is that of comely,
hospitable,
warm-hearted persons. One acquainted with them tells me that once he met
an Englishman in Alleghany. He was an old man, dejected, broken in spirit,
altogether a pitiable and hopeless object. My friend advised him to make
his way to a Shaker Society, of which there were then (and may be still)
two in the neighbourhood of Cincinnati. He was not much inspired by the
recommendation, but his abject condition overcame his scruples. A few
years
later he was seen on his way to Europe in search of his son, whom he
desired to bring to the society in which he had found refuge. On his way
he called
upon the friend, Robert Aspland Cooper, who had sent him to the Shakers.
His object was to leave a
well-stocked trunk in Alleghany until his return. He said the society had
supplied him with two, and one was more than enough. No longer dispirited
or
abject, his countenance beamed with happiness and gratitude as he spoke of
his Shaker friends, and his hope was to place his son among them, who
else probably had no future, save some Poor Law Union in England. Mrs.
Stanley appears to have had good reasons for disliking marriage. The
community is the bride they are advised to wed, which receives all the
more attention from the members, their affections not being diverted in
any human way.
The Rappites, though they have a disturbing name, have certainly proved
that even religious and restricted forms of co-operation conduce to
economy.
Their riches are celebrated by the friends of competition. They have
acquired the name
of Economites. They began in Pa. in 1803. These were they of whom Robert
Owen bought New Harmony town, and
35,000 acres of land in 1824. The term "Economites," which describes their
habits, is derived from the town of Economy, which they built eighteen
miles
below Alleghany. My correspondent, who resides near them, says they are
counted as millionaires, being reputed to be worth twenty millions of
dollars, or
about five millions English money, not much for a community to possess,
seeing that individuals of the commercial octopus
class often obtain more. But regarded as the surplus wealth of a people
who have all enjoyed complete prosperity—among whom no one has been a
pauper, no one poor, no one having cause or care for the future, it would
be difficult to find any nation so
wealthy. The Economites have been extensive manufacturers
of woollen goods and some silk goods. At present they manufacture nothing. The few death has left of them are past the time for
labour, and unless they take in new members their wealth will probably go
eventually to the State.
The Icarians under Cabet began their community in 1854. It had 6o members
and 1,829 acres of land. The Cabettians
were French Socialists. Cabet had no illusions like other social
leaders among his countrymen. His ideal was industrial. He sought to
improve life by labour and equity. Cabet made marriage obligatory in
Icaria.
Disciples of Josiah Warren and Stephen Pearl Andrews have written to me to
testify the growth of labour emancipation ideas in America—one proclaims
himself a two-meal-a-day convert, which does not of itself point to
prosperity. Whether this is an economical persuasion depends of course
upon the
quantity eaten, and upon this point no data has been forwarded
to me. If the limitation of meals arise from pecuniary scarcity, it is to
be hoped that Co-operation would supply him with the
means of trinitarian repasts. In England, co-operative stores
are favourable to those who eat as often as it is wise, and awards its
highest premiums to those members who do not neglect their meals. As a
rule, fat
reformers are found to be more congenial than lean ones; and they look
better at quarterly
meetings. The idea that mankind are to be saved by preaching merely
appears to be waning in America, and the conviction is growing that
criminals are made by bad social institutions, which ought to be
superseded.
America has been the experimenting ground of schemes, mostly of European
origin. It is only overcrowded cities, where competition is nearly used
up, or
has nearly used up the mass of the people, that new schemes of social life
are desired
or devised. Though caricatured by celibacy and defaced by religious and
sexual eccentricities, American communities show
what wealth, morality, and comfort can be had in them. The day will come
when men of good sense will add intelligence and art to the material
philosophy of Co-operation, and attain results that the people of many a
careworn town will gladly seek. Mr. Nordhoff, a Russian writer on American
communities, relates that many of them obtain a higher price in the
markets for their commodities than other firms, because their commodities can be trusted. Whether seeds of the ground or work of the loom,
they are known to be honest and good products. They are the only
dealers in America who have known how to
make honesty pay. Some say they are the only tradesmen who have attempted
it. Utopianism makes money—a thing not
believed in in England. Dr. B. W. Richardson has shown in his plan of a
Healthy Town, that if capital should take to moral ways, and put itself to
scientific uses, communities can be self-supporting, and made to pay in
Great Britain, without going to America to try them. The career of the Amanes or
Ebenezers shows abundantly that the crotcheteers of communism beat the
"practical" co-operators of this country.
The "Ebenezers" are a colony of religious Socialists, who consider
themselves under the guidance of an invisible spirit, who, however, seems
to
possess good business ability. Marriage is regulated by its consent; but
the spirit is prudent, and is
like Malthus in favour of deferred unions. This settlement is of German
origin, and numbered 600 when they arrived in
Buffalo from Hesse Dartnstadt in 1842. They date their origin
two hundred years back. It would be curious to know what they did, and why
they did it, and how they succeeded during the
two hundred years of their German career. Their success could never have
been what it has been in America, else we should have heard of them
in Europe. Their social scheme must be as old as that of Bellers, yet no
social reformers of this century have been aware of it. Their distinction,
if they
had any, at home would have been a fine illustration of the
practicability of social theories. They must have realised what we are
told is "contrary to human nature," according to those who are "set in
authority over us," or who have put themselves over us—for our good. These "Ebenezers," a somewhat nasal name, call themselves in lucid
intervals by
the prettier term of "Amanes." When they went to the United States they
settled upon an old Indian reservation of 6,000 acres, near Buffalo, New
York.
They found it too small for their numbers. About 1857 they moved west. They have now 30,000 acres at Amana, on the banks of the Iowa River, about
seventy miles from the Mississippi—woodland and prairie
pleasantly diversified. They have made progress in agriculture and other
industries. The colony numbers about 1,300 (1878). They have everything
in the way of property in common, but recognise the accepted form of
family life, and each family has
a separate house or apartments. Those who join the community contribute
their property to the common stock, and, if they become dissatisfied,
they receive back just what they
put in, without interest or wages. Property, therefore, is no bone of
contention, and no one can regard himself restricted when he is free to go
where he pleases. The objects of the Amanes society are religious
association, industrial and domestic co-operation, and the special
advancement of
the useful arts. The members dress plainly, live plainly, build plainly,
but substantially. They have extensive vineyards, make and drink wine and
lager
beer, but drunkenness is unknown among them. They appear to have no talent
for vices, commit no crimes,
and have no use for courts. There is, however, a Committee of Arbitration,
to settle differences when they arise. The government is administered and
the whole business of the community is supervised by a board of thirteen
trustees, who are elected by the votes of all the adult population, and
hold
the common property. Each department of industry has its manager, who is
responsible to the board of trustees, by whom he is appointed. This is
what
they have done in sixteen years: They found wild lands, and bridged the
rivers, made good roads, planted hedges of white willow, cut a canal
nearly nine
miles in length to supply their needed water power, erected flourishing
mills, woollen factories, machine shops, starch, sugar, and vinegar
manufactories,
all fitted out with fine machinery made by their own machinists. They have
built five villages on the tract, and two of them are stations for the
Rock Island
and Pacific Railroad, which come to their doors. They have good
school-houses, plain churches, and two grain elevators at the railroad
stations, and
buildings each of a capacity for storing 80,000 bushels of grain. The
children are kept at school until they are fourteen, and then they are
taught a trade or
agriculture, and their education is continued in night-schools. English is
taught, but German is the medium of communication in business and social
life.
Their religious services are simple, consisting principally of reading the
Scriptures, prayer, and singing, and they have some good voices, no
"School
Board difficulty," and no Mr. Forster. The women assist in light outdoor
work, especially in the vineyards. Early marriages are discouraged, and
men are
not considered of suitable age for wedlock until they attain the
maturity of thirty-five years. There is a great deal of intelligence in
this community, but no brilliancy. They have no "population question," no
impecuniosity, no misery such as develops such fine virtues among us, and
no calamities, from which English moralists deduce the salutary lessons of
responsibility. Having no ecclesiastical expounders to teach them the grounds of
duty, they are reduced to the necessity of doing right by good sense, and
have hitherto achieved no higher distinction than that of having attained
to a state of reasonable enjoyment and tame happiness, deprived of the
civilised
excitement of crimes; and their monotonous security is not even
variegated by murder. They affront the philosophical connoisseurs of
pleasure by being
satisfied with satisfaction, and contented with content.
In 1844 there appeared in America the Social Pioneer, representing the New
England Social Reform Society. Mr. J. P. Mendum, of Boston, was the
publisher, and Mr. Horace Seaver was the corresponding secretary—the same
two gentlemen honourably known as editors
of the Boston Investigator. In that year (1844) a Conference was held in
Phillip's Hall, Boston, with a view of promoting social re-organisation. This
Conference represented the pioneer community of Skaneateles, New York. One
of the persons present was Dr. Charles Knowlton, of Ashfield, Mass., the
gentleman whose name has
frequently appeared in this country. The most frequent and eloquent
speaker at the Convention was Mrs. Ernestine Rose, a Polish lady well
known
here. Mention is made then of her delicate health, which "prevented her
speaking with her wonted effect." It is pleasant to report that more than
thirty years
later she was still a speaker of remarkable power. Origen Bacheler, of
Rhode Island, famous as the opponent of Robert Dale Owen in the
best-expressed
discussions of modern times, appeared as an opponent in this Conference. Another adversary appeared who refused to give his name, except that he
was a disciple of Christ. The chairman (Captain Taylor) accordingly
announced that "the disciple of Christ had the floor." The resolutions
submitted to the
Conference amounted altogether to the amazing number of
nearly fifty. It would be wonderful, therefore, if they did not contain
some expressions to which some one could object, but they were remarkably
wise, temperate, moral, secular, and social in their purport. They mark
the progress of popular
opinion. Christians in America and England would be found now generally
claiming to agree with the spirit of them. Just as our co-operative colony
at Queenwood was disappearing, the most comprehensive Conference ever held in
favour of new forms of social life was held in America.
Mr. A. J. Macdonald, before mentioned, arrived at New Harmony in 1842,
fifteen years after Owen's time; he resided there two years as a
bookbinder. He
says after Owen's departure the majority of the population removed, and
that the remainder returned to Individualism, and settled as farmers and
mechanics in the ordinary way. In the preface to his unpublished work,
written shortly before his death, in 1854, Macdonald says he "imagined
mankind to
be better than they are, and was sanguine that communism would
speedily produce brilliant results, but that years of experience in
mingling with the world have shown him the 'stern reality,' and he hopes
that his work
will help to awaken dreamers." The fact is Macdonald was one of those
capricious enthusiasts who were hopeful when social schemes were incohate
and doubtful, and distrustful and despairing when they were really
succeeding around him. He was a Scotch emigrant, who began by having too
much
fervour for Socialism, and ended, like most persons of that class, with
having too little. He was, however, a man of original ways; he was a sort
of Old
Mortality of Co-operation, who visited the graveyards of communities in
America, deciphering the epitaphs of sixty-nine defunct phalanxes. Living
by his
trade, he obtained work in the neighbourhood of a communistic settlement,
and spent some time in learning the particulars of its history. He wrote
his account of it, and died leaving them in confusion. Mr. Noyes, into
whose hands they fell, has not printed them. They deserve publication, as
they
must contain curious facts unknown to any other author. Mr. Noyes, who has
a very mean opinion of social life, save the semi-spiritual and semi-sexual
one of the Oneida pattern, is not a trustworthy reporter of Macdonald's
MS. The account given me by my correspondent of New Harmony Society is
probably true. Every place in which schemes of undisciplined enthusiasm
have been put in operation, always prove reactionary in later years. The
residents are ashamed of the failure associated with their place, and in
their endeavours to repudiate it deny the existence of any liberalising
influences
left behind, or find some other paternity for them. All the persons I have
known who have lived to repudiate their early Socialistic faith—have
always
remained more liberal and enlightened than they would have been had they
never held it. It is singular how men of eminent experience take a partial
view
of the qualities of a nation, because it falls short of their ideal in a
particular respect in which they look for perfection. We know from
Madison's Report
"of the Convention that framed the famous Constitution of America," that
Washington said that "he believed all the virtues had left the land." Since,
however, modern Americans put down slavery in it, at such a cost of blood
and treasure, let us hope that some of the virtues have come back. Had
slavery existed in England for as long a time and to as great a
proportional extent, it would have found abler advocates among us than it
found in America,
and have cost a fiercer struggle to extinguish it. The population of New
Harmony in the year 1877 was but about 1,000. It had neither market nor
railroad, though they were expected. The place is not what Americans call
a "flourishing village." Tradesmen in it fear that the railroad (the
great bringer
of business) may injure them, which shows that England is not the only
place where antiquated notions can nestle.
________________________
Since this chapter was written an unforeseen co-operative settlement has
been founded near St. Louis, Mo., by N. O. Nelson, who has the practical
genius of Cabet, but who has achieved more than Cabet's success. |