[Previous
Page]
CHAPTER XXIII.
THE WHOLESALE SOCIETY
"In the moral world there is nothing impossible, if we
bring a thorough will to it. Man can do everything with himself, but
he must not attempt to do too much with others."—W. HUMBOLDT.
EVERYBODY understands the natural history of
discovery. Some one proposes to do something which it is thought
will be useful. It is at once declared to be absurd; then it is
found out that if it was done it would be dangerous; next it is proved
impossible, and that it was never done before, and it would have been done
if it had been possible. Nevertheless the proposers of the new thing
persist that it can be done. They come then to be designated by the
disagreeable names of "fanatics," impracticables, spoliators,
incendiaries, visionaries, doctrinaires, dreamers, and, generally,
troublesome and pestiferous persons. It is surmised that they are
probably of very bad morals, unsound in theology, and certainly ignorant
of the first principles of political economy. At length they
succeed. Their plan is then found to be eminently useful, very
desirable, and the source of profits and advantages to all concerned.
Then it is suddenly discovered that there never was anything new in
it—that it had always been known—that it is all as old as the hills, and
the valleys too—that it was recorded from the day history began, and,
doubtless, before. Those who reviled it, and distrusted it, now find
out that they always believed in it; and those who oppressed and denied it
now become aware that it was they who suggested it—that they were the
originators of it, and they who bore all the obloquy and opposition of
carrying it through, had really nothing to do with it. Something
like this is the history of the Co-operative Buying Society of Manchester,
which is a federation of stores for the wholesale purchase and
distribution of commodities for store sale.
When co-operative societies first began to multiply on the
Sussex coast, the idea of organising arrangements for buying first took
form. Dr. King was chief promoter of a plan for this purpose.
Lady Noel Byron contributed £300 to enable it to be carried into effect.
My townsman, Mr. William Pare, of Birmingham, was an advocate of a plan of
this nature for twenty years before it occupied the attention of Promoters
of Working Men's Associations in London, who were the first to practically
advance it.
The first official mention of a Co-operative Wholesale
Society dates as far back as 1832. The idea was started at the first
Manchester Conference, when it was thought that £500 would be sufficient
to set it going, and one was established at Liverpool which bore the name
of the North-West of England United Co-operative Company, its object being
to enable the societies to purchase their goods under more advantageous
terms. Mr. Craig relates that at a bazaar held in the Royal
Exchange, Liverpool, the rent of which was contributed by Lady Noel Byron,
delegates attended who brought goods which had been manufactured by
co-operators, and a large exchange was effected. There were linens
from Barnsley, prints from Birkacre, stuffs from Halifax, shoes from
Kendal, cutlery from Sheffield, and lace from Leicestershire. One
society had £400 worth of woollen goods, another had £200 of cutlery.
Some of the delegates were nearly entirely clad in clothes made by
co-operators. The Wigan Society had the possession of a farm, for
which they paid £600 a year.
But it was in Rochdale that the idea was destined to take
root and grow and be transplanted to Manchester. A mile and half or
more from Oldham, in a low-lying uncheerful spot, there existed, twenty
years ago, a ramshackle building know as Jumbo Farm. A shrewd
co-operator who held it, Mr. Boothman, had observed in the Shudehill
Market, Manchester, that it was great stupidity for five or six buyers of
co-operative stores to meet there and buy against each other and put up
prices, and he invited a number of them and others to meet at Jumbo Farm
on Sundays and discuss the Wholesale idea; and on Saturday nights at the
Oldham store at King Street, a curious visitor might have observed a solid
and ponderous load of succulent joints well accompanied, a stout cheese
being conspicuous, for Sunday consumption, during the Wholesale
discussion; for the hearty co-operators at jumbo had appetites as well as
ideas. Unaware what efforts had preceded theirs, they came to
imagine that they also devised the Wholesale. It was another mind
earlier occupied than theirs in attention to it, which had matured a
working conception of it.
Jumbo Farm is nearly effaced or built over now. It had
a dreary, commonplace look when I last saw it. Though I do not
believe, as certain old frequenters of that jaggling spot do, that the
gravitation, the circulation of the blood, and Queen Cassiopia's chair
were first discovered there, I respect it because useful discussions were
held there under Mr. Boothman's occupancy; and I was glad to hear from Mr.
Marcroft authentic particulars how the joints got there on the good days
of debate, when co-operators were "feeling their way"—and, what showed
their good sense, eating their way too; for lean reformers seldom hit upon
fat discoveries. There were and still are two great stores in
Oldham—Greenacres and King Street. Greenacres has never carried out
Sunday gatherings on any occasion. King Street Cooperative Society
has done so for over twenty-five years, and many of their best and most
successful projects have first been talked of at these Sunday meetings. That society has probably the largest number of members who are ever
trying to get new light to better understand what is possible and
immediately practicable. The members have no dogmatic opinions as to
religion or politics, but are prepared to hear all men, and change action
when duty and interest lead, reverencing the old and accepting the new. For all this, as well as for its interest in the commissariat of
Jumbo,
King Street shall be held in honour among stores! The Christian Socialist
periodical, of 1852, published an account of a conference held in
Manchester, when Mr. Smithies, of Rochdale, was appointed one of a
committee,
of which
Mr. L. Jones was also a member, to take steps for establishing a general depôt in Manchester for supplying the store with and provisions. At that
time Mr. L. Jones groceries plan, [181] which contained the elementary ideas of
an organised depôt so far as experience then indicated them. Thus the idea
had from the beginning been in the air. Costly attempts were made to
localise it in London in 1850. A few years later Rochdale conducted a
wholesale department in connection with its store for the supply of
Lancashire and Yorkshire. But it became apparent that the increasing
stores of the country could never be supplied adequately by a department
of any store, and that Rochdale having co-operated with the Wholesale
Society in London, devised and carried forward a working plan suited to
the needs and means of the stores in Lancashire and Yorkshire. They
trimmed the lamp afresh, and for some ten years they kept it burning: its
light enabling other pioneer co-operators to see their way to founding a
new, separate, and more comprehensive society, which came to bear the name
of the North of England Wholesale. Mr. Crabtree was on the committee of
the Wholesale in 1865, the same year in which Mr. Nuttall first joined it. Mr. Crabtree recalls a series of public facts which prove that by all
contemporaries best acquainted with the subject, Mr. Abraham Greenwood, of
Rochdale, was the chief founder of the Wholesale. [182] Mr. Crabtree sets
forth that "in the Co-operator for March, 1863 (vol. 3), Mr. Greenwood
propounded his plan for a Wholesale Agency, which, with some
modifications, formed the basis of their organisation." Mr. Nuttall's
paper, read at the London Congress, in 1869, makes reference to the
efforts of 1856, and shows that its promoters failed to agree as to the
best means of raising the capital. Particulars of this are given on page
39 in the Congress Report, and on page 40 Mr. Nuttall gives credit to Mr.
Greenwood for having proposed a plan which was ultimately adopted. Instead
of charging a commission upon goods bought, they charged for their goods a
price which covered the commission, and was intended only to be sufficient
to cover expenses incurred.
The Wholesale scheme in its inception and careful steps for carrying it
out in 1864, is a good example of the constructive co-operators' methods. Thrice the attempt had been made, thrice it had discouragingly failed. More than thirty years had intervened since the project was
first launched. It had been lost like a ship at sea, but had not
foundered, and was heard of again. Again and
it went out of sight and record, and again reappeared. Greenwood examined
the vessel, found its sailing powers were all right, but it was sent out
to coasts where no business could
be done, and consequently could not keep up a working crew, and the ship
could never get back to port without assistance.
The reader knows from public report what the expenses usually are of
promoting and establishing an insurance or other company. Many might think
that the magical "twopence," out of which Rochdale finance arose,
would be insufficient here, but the actual levy fell very much below, as
the following circular, sent to each society by Mr. William Cooper when
the Wholesale was resolved on, will show:—
"At a conference of delegates from industrial and provident co-operative
societies, held at the King Street Stores meeting-room, Oldham, on
December 25, 1862, it was resolved:—'That all co-operative societies be
requested to contribute one farthing per member, to meet the expenses that
may arise.' The purposes for which the money is required are—to meet the
expenses of the committee in carrying out the resolutions of the
Conference, viz.:—To remedy a few defects of the Act of 1862 in the
present session of Parliament; to prepare plans for a central agency and
wholesale depôt;
consider plans for insurance, assurance, and guarantee, in connection with
the co-operative societies. Therefore your society is respectfully
solicited for the above contribution of one farthing per member." [183]
This Wholesale tax, when it was gathered in, would have
been of small avail had not strong and clear proofs of advantage been drawn up
and presented to the confederators. The benefits calculated by Mr.
Greenwood as likely to arise (and which have been realised) he foretold as
follows:—
"1st. Stores are enabled, through the agency, to purchase more
economically than heretofore, by reaching the best markets.
"2nd. Small stores and new stores are at once put in a good position, by
being placed directly (through the agency) in the best markets, thus
enabling them to sell as cheap as any first-class shopkeeper.
"3rd. As all stores have the benefit of the best markets, by means of the
agency, it follows that dividends paid by stores must be more equal than
heretofore; and, by the same means, dividends considerably augmented.
"4th. Stores, especially large ones, are able to carry on their businesses
with less capital. Large stores will not, as now, be necessitated, in
order to reach the minimum prices of the markets, to purchase goods they
do not require for the immediate supply of their members.
"5th. Stores are able to command the services of a good buyer, and will
thus save a large amount of labour and expense, by one purchaser buying
for some 150 stores; while the whole amount of blundering in purchasing at
the commencement of a co-operative store is obviated."
Never was a great movement created by clearer arguments or a smaller
subscription. The Wholesale began at a bad time, when the cotton famine
prevailed, and the first half-year it lost money, but the second half-year
its directors contrived to clear off the loss, and pay a dividend of 12s.
6d. per cent. With an average capital of £2,000, and working expenses
amounting to £267, the company transacted business to the amount of
£46,000. The economy of capital and labour thus achieved was
unprecedented, and a proof of the power and advantage of the ready-money rule. Such were the results
accomplished by the Farthing Federation in 1864.
Within twelve months, Lord Brougham (than whom none knew better how to
appreciate the significance of such a step) spoke of it as one "which, in
its consequence, would promote Co-operation to a degree almost incalculable." When
Mr. Horace Greeley was last in England, he inquired of me
as was his wont with Cobbett-like keenness, as to the progress of
Co-operation. From information he received from others also he wrote an
account of the Wholesale in the New York Tribune, in which he confirmed
Lord Brougham's estimation of its importance.
Scotland has a Wholesale Society of its own, which is
situated in Glasgow. The Manchester Wholesale was solicited to
establish a branch there, but ultimately the Scottish co-operators
established one themselves. In 1873 the new warehouse of the
Scottish Wholesale Society, a large commanding
building, was opened in the Paisley Road, Glasgow. Mr. Alexander James Meldrum was the President, and James Borrowman, Manager.
The first year of the Scottish Wholesale Society they did business to the
amount of £81,000. In
the fifth year £380,000. Their capital the first year was £5,000, in the
fifth £37,000. Their total divisible profit, exclusive of interest,
exceeded £8,000 in the first five years,
In 1863, Ellen Mason, writing from Whitfield Rectory, remarked that "a
Wholesale Depot at Newcastle would be an immense boon to us." Many years
later the appeal was listened to, as was also an application made in
London, where a branch was established at 118, Minories, [184] with great
advantage to the Southern stores. In 1865 an application was made from New
South Wales to the Wholesale, to consider whether the Co-operative Society
of Sydney could not purchase through it.
Its method of business is: With the first order a remittance must be
enclosed sufficient to cover the value of the goods. Future accounts must
be paid on receipt of invoice, or within seven days from the date; but if
not paid within fourteen days no more goods will be supplied until such
overdue accounts are paid.
The shares, which were £5 each, were issued on condition that a society
took out one for each ten members belonging to it, increasing the number
annually as its members increase. [185]
The progress of the Wholesale during fourteen years from 1864 to 1867 the
following table tells. The figures are taken from the Rochdale
Pioneers' Almanac of 1878:—
Year. |
No. of
Members in Societies which are Shareholders. |
£5 shares taken up. |
Capital, Share, and Loan. (£) |
Value of Goods Sold. (£) |
Net profit. (£) |
1864 |
18,337 |
|
2,456 |
51,858 |
267 |
1865 |
24,005 |
|
7,182 |
120,755 |
1,859 |
1866 |
31,030 |
|
10,936 |
175,420 |
2,310 |
1867 |
57,443 |
|
24,208 |
255,779 |
3,452 |
1868 |
74,494 |
|
28,148 |
381,464 |
4,925 |
1869 |
77,686 |
|
37,785 |
469,171 |
3,584 |
1870 |
87,854 |
|
43,950 |
653,608 |
6,818 |
1871 |
114,184 |
5,821 |
49,262 |
727,737 |
8,038 |
1872 |
131,191 |
6,651 |
133,493 |
1,049,394 |
10,468 |
1873 |
163,661 |
12,894 |
196,578 |
1,531,950 |
14,044 |
1874 |
192,457 |
16,641 |
228,817 |
1,925,548 |
19,963 |
1875 |
241,829 |
21,473 |
360,527 |
2,103,226 |
23,816 |
1876 |
274,874 |
24,658 |
399,255 |
2,644,322 |
34,808 |
1877 |
273,351 |
24,850 |
414,462 |
2,791,477 |
33,274 |
In 1877 there were 588 societies buying from the Wholesale. In the table
above the reader will see the number of members in these Societies that
exceeded 273,000. The Reserved Capital of the Wholesale is £27,898. This
Society had (1878) 32 buyers and salesmen, including those stationed at
Cork, Limerick, Kilmarnock, Tipperary, Waterford, Tralee, Armagh, and New
York. The large Reserve Fund is yearly increased so as to render every
department of the Society secure. One department, that of banking, has
grown to such dimensions that its separation from the Wholesale is advised
by the most prudent friends of the Society, and that it be conducted on
recognised banking principles.
The fifty-first quarterly balance-sheet of this society was described by a
writer in the Newcastle Chronicle ( 1877) as a huge folio pamphlet of
twenty-four pages, filled with all sorts of accounts and statistics
rendered with painstaking minuteness. The Wholesale serves 22 counties,
besides parts of Scotland, Ireland, and the Isle of Man.
The total cash received from the whole area during one quarter was
£815,411, yielding a dividend to the customer societies of £6,211. The
expense of management for the quarter was £6,223. The smallest return is
from Cornwall, amounting to £3 10s. 4d. The Wholesale holds land and
buildings and the ship Plover of the estimated value £72,130. [186] Its
productive establishments were then a boot factory at Leicester, a biscuit
factory at Crumpsall, and soap factory at Durham. Besides these direct and
exclusive investments the Wholesale held shares in seventeen manufacturing, printing, coal, and insurance companies. [187]
Members of this society, being stores, the division of
profits is made after the manner of stores. In the productive
work-shops owned by the Wholesale there is no division of profits with
labour. In some businesses custom is great and labour small, and in
others labour is large; but labour in every productive society should have representation on the
directorate. It is not possible to prescribe an inflexible law of
division; but what should be inflexible is the partnership of labour. There should be set apart in workshops, as in stores, funds for
educational purposes. It does not pay to have fools for members, and it
is shabby to depend for information upon papers written and speeches given
by charity.
Every producing society should be co-operative, self-acting, and
self-sustaining. Like the products of Nature, every seed of organised
industry, wherever it took root, would yield perfect fruit in every place; then federation will be the federation of equals gaining like an army by
combination, perfect in individual discipline, and able, each like the
English at Inkermann, to make a stand on its own account. Under a true
co-operative system factories and industrial works will rear workmen who
will have the old ambition of skilled craftsmen. The means of social
education should be available in every mill and mine, factory and farm.
If the directors of the Wholesale add to their other great achievements
the revival of participation in the profits of labour in their productive
works, they may increase their profits, command the goodwill of the whole
labouring community, and win a more splendid repute than was accomplished
by Robert Owen at New Lanark, which subsisted for three years.
How difficult it was in the early days of Co-operation to get persons
qualified to buy! Buyers, like poets, seem to be born, not made. They must
possess the tact of the market. It is of small use that a man has
money to buy with, unless he knows where to find the right dealers in the right thing. A mechanic,
while confined to workshops, does not often know where
to go to buy. There are certain tea fields in the world known to produce
certain qualities of tea, and certain houses
get possession of them. Some men who do know where to look for the article
they want, probably do not know it when
they see it. A man who is a great tea buyer has tea in his blood: just as
famous mechanics who have steel in their blood, know metals by instinct,
as some men do colours or
textures, or as artists do forms and tints. I know one coffee roaster in
Manchester who has coffee in his blood, and I never
knew but one man in London who had. Sugars are also a
special field for the exercise of natural taste. The Wholesale Society
engage, or create, or nurture a class of great buyers, to ensure to the
humblest store advantages they could not command for themselves. The officers of the Wholesale submit any doubtful
food to the operation of the public analyst. Sometimes a store will report
through its local buyer that it can purchase much cheaper than the society
can buy through the Wholesale. Specimens of what has been so bought are
asked for, when, on sending it to the analyst, it has transpired that the
cheapness was owing to the commodity being fraudulently adulterated. Local
buyers are subjected to so many temptations, by commissions clandestinely
or openly offered by agents seeking orders, that many who are men of
honesty when they take office cease to be so in a short time. Unless the
store finds a buyer of unusual integrity who resists doing what he sees
others do [188], a store must pay a higher salary to
place him above
temptation. The Wholesale Society has been a great source of fiduciary
morality and economy by affording the stores a buying agency.
A considerable sum of money has been spent with a view of instituting a
Mississippi Valley Trading Company. A deputation was sent to New Orleans
to promote that object, and a scheme promoted of International
Co-operation between England and America, officially brought under the
notice of
the Grangers of the United States at their Annual Conferences.
At a quarterly meeting of the Wholesale several hundred delegates
assemble, and a more striking spectacle of the capacity of the working
class for business, when their minds are set upon it by self-training and
intelligent interest, is not to be witnessed in England or elsewhere. Between the House of Commons of to-day and the Wholesale Conference
there is an instructive comparison. The delegates of the Wholesale present
an appearance of more alertness, brightness, and resolute attention to
business than is to be seen in the
House of Commons. In that House of 670 members there are not more than 70
who attend earnestly to business. There are about 100 who attend pretty
well to their own business, and the remainder attend to anything else when
it occurs to
them. At the Wholesale Conference all the members attend
to the business. The Chairman knows what the business is
and accelerates it if it loiters on the way. Each delegate has in his
hands a huge-sized folio covered with a wilderness of figures; and when
one page is exhausted the rustle of leaves turning over simultaneously in
every part of the hall is not unlike the rising of a storm at sea, or a
descent of asteroids in November, or the vibration of silk when the rush
of ladies takes place at her Majesty's Drawing-Room. The directors of the
Wholesale, like Ministers in Parliament, are all on the platform, ready to
answer questions put, and sometimes have
replies on hand to questions which are not put. In ever every part of the
large hall in Balloon Street, or Leman Street, the voices of questioners
and critics break out in quick succession. No body of the industrious
classes in England excel a Conference of the Wholesale; nowhere else are
the delegates more numerous; nowhere else is every one better able to
make a speech; every one having some business knowledge and experience of
the branch he represents.
CHAPTER XXIV.
LONDON CO-OPERATION—THE REVOLT OF THE GROCERS
"Folly is a contagious disease, but there is difficulty in catching
wisdom."—G. J. H.
CO-OPERATION has produced two distinct and
protracted revolts—one of the grocers, another of their customers. The
first revolt is very little known, and none are now alive who were
observant of it, or actors in it. Co-operation cannot be said to be a
disturbing influence since it seeks amity, and has always been pacific;
but private traders have been perturbed concerning it for a century. The
first revolt of the grocers against it took place before the days of the
first Reform Bill. We know tradesmen conspire against it; when Mr. Baliol
Brett (since Mr. Justice Brett) went down to oppose Mr. Cobden at
Rochdale, his chief charge against the great free trader was that he was
friendly to Co-operation. At the general election of 1872 candidates well
disposed towards it were reticent concerning it, and others not reticent,
who had held seats in the previous Parliament, lost them. The knowledge
that they had stood up for fair play for co-operators proved fatal to
them. Co-operation we know has been the perplexity of two Governments,
Chancellors of the Exchequer have a terror of deputations praying to have
Co-operation put down. The Government of Mr. Gladstone carefully abstained
from saying anything in its favour, and that of Lord Beaconsfield
abstained from doing anything against it. Co-operation was said to be
impossible; and if not impossible impractical; nevertheless efforts are
constantly made to prevent the impracticable from being put into practice.
Adversaries among shopkeepers have shown skill in preserving
themselves from the infection of wisdom. Though confident in their
superiority as trained competitors, they show distress at the appearance
of amateurs in the field, as the Church clergy did, when the untutored
Wesleyans took to preaching on the village green. It was beneath the
clerical dignity to fear competition. They strengthened it by
showing terror at it, as tradesmen do at Co-operation.
The Co-operation of our time, imagined to be a recent
invention, is built upon the ruins of extinct movements buried out of
sight and knowledge of the commercial classes of to-day, under forests of
forgotten publications as completely as Pompei under the ashes of
Vesuvius. Strange is it to see grocers and tradesmen descending into
the streets, to arrest the progress of Co-operation, holding indignation
meetings in the anterooms of the Government in Downing Street, and to read
that their forefathers in business were equally excited a century ago.
When the Union Mill was first commenced in Devonport,
adjoining Plymouth, in 1815, the members had no mill, bake-house, or shop
of their own, in which to make up or sell their flour. They rented a
small store, in which to sell their bread, and were dependent on a baker
for making it. The bakers soon combined against them, and wrote to
the Admiralty to put them down. The Government never appear to have
been very anxious to take the part of one set of tradesmen against
another. A venerable survivor, who was 84 years old in 1863,
mortgaged a house as he had to raise £600 to enable a new society to be
established in the town. [189]
The British Association (for the Promotion of Co-operation)
of 1830 brought under the notice of its members "with extreme regret that
an ignorant yet powerful band of petty shopkeepers at Hampstead, has been
successful by bribes and cunning in frustrating the attempt of some
co-operators in that place to hold a public meeting, and that the
parochial authorities of Tunbridge Wells and of Thurmaston, in
Leicestershire, have withdrawn the trifling pittance given by the parish
to some poor people who were making attempts to relieve themselves from so
degrading a dependence for bread. Others threatened with like
privations have been obliged to withdrawn from membership of the
co-operative societies, and remain a burden to their parishes." [190]
The probability is that the shopkeepers who happened to be guardians were
willing to throw upon their neighbours this liability in order to protect
their own interests at the counter. In other places local influence
was brought to bear upon officers of the Government, and representations
were made to them on behalf of grocers. At Godalming, in Surrey, the
trustees of a Co-operative Association in 1830 were refused a licence for
the sale of tea by the Excise officers, to prevent them beginning the
grocery trade, which would interfere with that of retail dealers close by.
Whereupon Mr. G. R. Skene wrote to the Board of Excise, who behaved very
well in the matter. The persons refusing the licence received a
severe reprimand, and a licence was instantly granted with apologies, and
an illegal fee returned. At Poole a threatened extortion of the
parish rates was made upon the co-operators with a view to deter them, but
it was successfully resisted. Mr. Skene was the Secretary of the
British Association for Promoting Co-operative Knowledge, which met in
London.
The grocers being personally affected by co-operative
shop-keeping have been oftener before the public in opposition to it, but
they have not been more unpleasant in their action than manufacturers, or
farmers, or other classes, whose trade interests have been affected by any
rival movement. The clergy have been quite as disagreeable to
Dissenting ministers, and have appealed to Parliament to suppress them
oftener than shop-keepers have appealed for public aid. There seems
to be no difference in the practices of gentlemen and poor men where trade
interests are threatened. Employers, capitalists, and even bishops
and noblemen, were all as spiteful and as offensive as workmen, to whom
lower wages meant disease and home misery. From 1826 to 1836
numerous instances occur of the "superior" classes being engaged in
strikes and rattening and picketing as against the lower classes.
The discreditable practices are solely imputed to working men and trade
unionists. Grocers have been the most noisy, but co-operators have
been attacked by more dangerous adversaries.
Mr. William Carson, a delegate to the Third Co-operative
Congress, held in London in April, 1832, related that "he held a situation
with a highly respectable architect employed by the Commissioners for
building churches, amongst whom were several bishops and others of the
aristocracy. His discharge was sent him although he had a wife and
large family to maintain, because he had rendered himself obnoxious to the
Commissioners by the active exertions he had made in aid of Co-operation."
Upon the architect appealing to Commissioners on Mr. Carson's behalf,
telling them of the situation in which he would be placed if they were
determined upon his discharge, the reply was "he must be discharged and
they would bear the responsibility." Whatever injustice these
inspired gentlemen practised, they were pretty safe, and they knew it.
Mr. E Taylor, delegate from Birkacre, Lancashire, who
represented a society of more than three hundred persons, whose premises
for printing silks and cottons stood at a rental of £600, stated that they
suffered greatly from the jealousies of capitalists and masters who had
tampered with their landlord to get them turned out of their premises. [191]
These cases were oft reported. The jealous adversary generally
succeeded.
In the days of the Cotton Famine in Lancashire and Yorkshire
the shopkeepers on relief committees oft behaved with incredible
shabbiness to the co-operators. In many towns they caused the
co-operators to be refused any participation in the funds publicly
subscribed for the relief of the distressed.
Liberals have always been more or less prompt in befriending
Co-operation; but tradesmen, in their hostility to it, have always assumed
that the Conservatives could be depended upon to put it down. It is
therefore justice to record the honourable letter which the late Earl
Derby wrote at the opening of the new store at Prestwich, dated Knowsley,
January 6, 1864. His Lordship said to Mr. Pitman, "If any persons
have been led to believe that I look coldly on the co-operative movement,
they are greatly mistaken. It has always appeared to me to be well
calculated to encourage in the operative classes habits of frugality,
temperance, and self-dependence; and if the managers of these societies
conduct them prudently, not entering into wild speculations, and retaining
in hand a sufficient amount of reserved capital to meet casual
emergencies, they cannot fail to exercise a beneficial influence upon the
habits of the population, both morally and physically." Lord Derby
was a man of honour, he might sincerely sacrifice his country was to his
principles, but he never sacrificed his convictions to his party.
Passages have been published from time to time by men of
eminence or influence, favourable to Co-operation. Among these were
John Stuart Mill, the present Lord Derby (1877), Mr. Gladstone, Professor
Francis William Newman, Professor Frederick Denison Maurice, Canon
Kingsley, the Rev. William Nassau Molesworth, Lord Brougham, Mr. Bright,
Mr. Cobden, and William Chambers. Mr. Mill's opinion, written at the
opening of the Liverpool Provident Association, is remarkable, like most
statements of his, for its completeness and comprehensiveness. He
said, "Of all the agencies which are at work to elevate those who labour
with their hands, in physical condition, in social dignity, and in those
moral and intellectual qualities on which both the others are ultimately
dependent, there is none so promising as the present co-operative
movement. Though I foresaw, when it was only a project, its great
advantages, its success has thus far exceeded my most sanguine
expectations, and every year adds strength to my conviction of the
salutary influence it is likely to exercise over the destinies of this and
other countries."
It was the perilous but honourable practice of Mr. Robert
Lowe when he was Chancellor of the Exchequer, to give what information he
could which might serve a deputation waiting upon him. Had he talked
a few platitudes to them and left them to believe he would do what he
could when he knew he could do nothing, he had been more popular but less
deserving of honour. He told the deputation from the National
Chamber of Trade, introduced by Mr. W. H. Smith, M.P., later, Lord of the
Admiralty, that "The only way to defeat these societies was by competing
with them in the market, and if they were in a condition to do that, let
them do so, and combine together, and offer to the public as good terms as
these societies did."
Mr. Gladstone, in his correspondence with Messrs. Evison and
Barter in 1868, told them with like wisdom and honesty "Long credits mean
large loans by men in business out of their trading capital. This
system aggravates the risk of had debts, which form an additional charge
to a good debtor: and it is connected with a general irregularity and
uncertainty which must also be paid for. I cannot help thinking that
traders are in fault also, and that much might be done by a vigorous
effort, and by combination among traders in favour of ready-money
dealings."
Some of the deputation to the Liberal ministry were incited,
for political reasons, to elicit expressions of opinion that might be used
to influence shopkeepers' votes at the election. For tradesmen to
ask the Government for aid against competitors was to confess their
incompetence to conduct their own business on trade principles. Most
of them knew that the Tories could no more interfere on their behalf than
the Liberals, and Mr. Gladstone was more their friend than they deserved
to find him in the advice he gave them. He saw that if the chief
grocers would combine together and open a large ready-money store,
guaranteeing the best provisions, they might rival the stores, and in some
cases supersede them; making sufficient profit to share it with
purchasers.
Professor Thorold Rogers states—in the address delivered by
him at the London Congress in 1875—that, "from careful inquiries made by
him of large manufacturers in many branches of productive industry, as to
the cost at which these articles were charged in their books when they
left the workshop, compared with the prices charged to the purchaser by
the retail trader, he found that the additions made, as the charge of
distribution, very commonly doubled the price of the article." Not
that the retail trade gained the enormous addition, but that the cost of
distribution is increased from excess of middlemen. Co-operators are
often under the illusion that their savings represent the profit of the
shopkeeper, whereas they also represent the cost which the shopkeeper
incurs. The co-operator gains what the shopkeeper loses, and they do
not. Herein the shopkeepers by combination can gain equally.
The Civil Service Co-operative Society have a place of
business in the Haymarket, yet every day, nearly from top to the bottom of
the street, as great a crowd of carriages of the nobility are to be seen
as are to be found in Piccadilly, at Fortnum and Mason's the day before
the Derby day. As many footmen surround the doors of this Civil
Service Store as are to be found round Swan and Edgar's, or Waterloo
House, in Cockspur Street. Yet at this Haymarket store there are
more forms to be gone through, and more trouble to be encountered in
buying a pound of butter than in obtaining a dividend from the Bank of
England. This is not all the wonder. The Haymarket is not a
place of sweetest repute. True, there are honest houses and
residents of good fame in it; yet it remains suspicious to hear a young
marchioness accosted in Rotten Row by a young nobleman, who assures her he
has not had the pleasure to see her since he met her in the Haymarket.
It could hardly be any light or unimportant thing which induces ladies of
"high degree" to subject themselves to be addressed in terms which are
considered to require explanation. What is it that attracts these
illustrious customers; and induces them to incur all this conspicuousness,
suspicion, discomfort, and fatigue, but the satisfaction of providing
their houses with articles of consumption which they think they can depend
upon for purity, and obtain at moderate charges? There is no
instance in the whole of London of any shop so unattractively situated
commanding customers so numerous and so distinguished. This shows
the grocers what they have to do.
Advantage comes to a great store saving the rents of a
hundred shops, a hundred servants, the support of a hundred proprietors,
in addition to saving the taxes and advertisements of as many places.
The cost of small shops is very great to the public, but the gain to the
shopkeeper is little. The greater part of what he receives in price
is lost on the way by his many expenses in making his little sales, that
there scarcely remains in his hands enough to keep him in his useful but
often needless calling. It is only this little profit of the shop
keeper that the co-operator intercepts. He gathers up what never
comes into the shopkeeper's hands. The unseeing saying that "what
the co-operator gains comes out of the shopkeeper's pocket" causes the
shopkeeper to think himself five times more harmed than is true, and it
conceals from the co-operator that four out of five portions of his gain
are not won in a victory over the tradesmen, but by his joining in
business with his fellows, by faithfulness to his own store and by equity
in trade. If every shopkeeper was abolished to-morrow by Act of
Parliament, co-operators would gain little. Co-operative prosperity
does not come by prayer, but by prudence; not by caprice, but by concert.
It is seeing this clearly, seeing it constantly, seeing it always, which
constitutes the education of the co-operator.
Pictures have been drawn by shopkeepers of every tradesman
being bankrupt and the town in the hands of the co-operators. Of
course this never happened, but it was thought all the more likely by the
excited, because it never could happen. An enterprising friend of
mine, [192] wishing me to name
some town where he might open a new shop, I at once said, "Rochdale, and
nestle near the store, that is the best place for a new shopkeeper."
"Well," he answered, "any one who looks about towns to see what is the
matter with them, and what openings they offer, sees what people living in
them do not see, because they are so obvious, and the obvious is the last
thing people do see—but you must be wrong about Rochdale." My answer
was, "Near a store is the place for a new shop to pay. First, a
number of outsiders will buy off you, to spite the store. Next, half
the co-operators will buy off you themselves, for half the co-operators
always think the goods in the shops are cheaper and better than those in
their own stores." Every director of a store knows this. He
has heard it at quarterly meetings a hundred times. Half the stores
do not buy themselves off their own Wholesale Society, because they
believe they "can do better elsewhere." Half the members of any
store are dividend hunters—not a bad sort of hunting in its way—and I am
glad that co-operative stores are good hunting-grounds for the working
classes; but an ignorant hunter is like an untrained setter, he has not an
educated nose. He does not know where to find the bird; or he starts
it foolishly, whereby it gets away. I went the other day into one of
the three greatest stores in the country. My first question, after a
long absence, was, as is my wont, "Have you the Co-operative News
about (theJournal of the societies)? How many purchasers enter this
shop in a week?" "Four thousand," was the reply." "How many
Co-operative News do you sell?" "Oh, FOUR DOZEN!"
"Yes," I answered, "that statement wants a great big 'O' to preface it.
That means that out of every 4,000 members of the store 3,952 believe they
can be co-operators and hunt dividends better without co-operative
knowledge than with it." In the pork and butter shop, where they had
1,000 customers a week, they sold one dozen Co-operative News only.
There was the same discreditable proportion of non-intelligent members
found all over the store. The dividend hunters, their name is
legion, the intelligence hunters—are twelve in the thousand. Since
that time that cultivated store has lost a great pot of gold at one
swoop—enough to have bought a copy of the Co-operative News every
week for every member for the last ten years, and given each a penny with
it to read it. Had they done this they would have now £30,000 in
hand out of vanished funds. "Therefore, my teetotal, energetic
manufacturing friend, if thou wantest to make money, open thy shop under
the shadow of a great store, and if only half the unreading members buy of
thee, thou wilt make a fortune long before they take in their own paper.
Besides, put into thy account the mass of people who do not understand
co-operation. In towns like Liverpool and Birmingham the memory of
it has almost died out. A mighty and historic store may have 10,000
members in a population of 100,000 inhabitants. That leaves
nine-tenths of all purchasing people to the tradesmen. Does not that
give you an abounding chance? Then remember that the majority of
persons use their brains so little, that the avenues of their minds are
blocked up. When they were born there was no School Board to keep
the entrance of their intelligence clear, and put something through it.
Never fear, shop-keeping will last your time." My friend followed my
advice, and prospered exceedingly. A shopkeeper who knows his
business can hold his business. It is the other sort who turn into
querulous complainants.
There is a saying, "Mad as a hatter." There is nobody
so mad as a grocer, when he imagines a co-operator is after him. Yet
the better sort of shopkeepers are among the best friends co-operators
have found. They have generously taught workmen the art of keeping
shops. In many an emercency they have given counsel and aid. I
know it, because I have asked it for the aid of young stores. In
Scotland and England and I know many shopkeepers—men of genius in their
way, masters of their business. Their service of the public is a
fine art, and buyers of taste will always go to them. The
co-operators are not born who will harm them. Shopkeepers have no
more reason to be afraid of Co-operation, than inn-keepers have to be
afraid of the Permissive Bill. Of course there will be mad publicans
as well as demented grocers.
The grocers set Sir Thomas Chambers to make an inquiry in
Parliament whether the Government could not put down Civil Service
Co-operative Supply Associations. Any clear-headed co-operator, for
a moderate fee, would put them up to a thing or two which would endanger
the best Civil Service Co-operative Society in the metropolis. All
Sir Thomas Chambers could do, if he got his way, would be to spite the
Civil Service gentlemen. Once they were removed other men of
business would be put in their places.
The Right Hon. C. B. Adderley, M.P. (Conservative), attended
a meeting of the Ladywood Co-operative Society in Birmingham, 1869, and
made a speech strongly in its favour, and said that "God intended the
whole world to be one great association of co-operation." Mr.
Sampson Lloyd, M.P. for Plymouth (also a Conservative, elected in lieu of
Mr. Morrison, the former Liberal member, who was charged with sympathy
with Co-operation), also sent a letter to the Ladywood meeting in approval
of its object. Mr. William Howitt afterwards made it an occasion to
thank God that Mr. Adderley had discovered, like many other statesmen and
landholders, that Co-operation is a great "school of natural instruction."
[193] The Liberals,
being more in favour of self-action and self-help among the people, have
been more friendly to co-operators. Certainly the only members of
Parliament who have been active on their behalf, and who have made
sacrifices for their success, have been Liberals.
Civil Service Stores, Army and Navy Supply Associations, have
done grocers harm in London, and not the Working Class Stores which Mr.
Morrison and Mr. Hughes supported. Yet they were sacrificed by the
undiscerning shop-keeping elector who gave his vote to the real enemy.
Mr. Hughes was certainly kept out of Parliament at Marylebone through the
reputed resentment of the shopkeepers.
Mr. Walter Morrison, M.P., wrote a remarkable letter to the
Daily News in 1873, in reply to some editorial comments, critical
but not unfriendly. Mr. Morrison said: "You seem to think that the
societies there represented conduct their trade after the fashion of the
Civil Service societies in London. I venture to assert that the very
large majority of those who have at heart the continued prosperity of
co-operative societies deprecate that manner of doing their trade as
earnestly as any retail shopkeeper. We hold that it is unfair to the
honest tradesman, who sells genuine and unadulterated goods at a fair
living profit, that it degrades Co-operation into a mere mercantile
machine for cheapening the price of goods. From the Land's End to
John o' Groat's there is not a workman's retail co-operative store which
attempts to undersell the tradesmen of the locality; when tradesmen have
combined to ratten the store out of the district by underselling it, the
stores have not retaliated in kind."
Though Conservative candidates have profited by opposing, or
conniving at opposition to co-operators, it ought to be said to the honour
of the Conservative press that it has never concealed its approval of the
principle, even as respects Productive Co-operation as applied to
manufactures, which fewer persons can be found to speak approvingly of.
The Standard said, before a general election:—
"Co-operation, on the other hand, though possibly too weak
a remedy to be relied upon altogether, is the best device for putting
labour, more or less, on a level with capital, which has ever been
attempted. As far as it goes it is thoroughly healthy in its action.
The co-operative factory . . . competes with the private capitalist, and
tends to keep up, at their highest possible level, the terms offered to
the workmen in return for his labour." [194]
This was plainly said, the reader can see. The
tradesman, therefore, has no ground for treating Co-operation as a
political question.
CHAPTER XXV.
LONDON CO-OPERATION,—THE REVOLT OF THE CUSTOMER
"The friends of order became insurgents when a real
grievance came home to them. Partizans and apologists of trading
confiscation, who regarded it as the reward assigned by Nature to
successful competition, so long as they shared the spoil, discovered it to
be a shameful exaction when they were subjects of it."—Eccentricities
of Opinion (unpublished). G. J. H.
THE second revolt produced by Co-operation proved to
be a revolt of customers. This long-foreseen but late-arriving
insurgency, led to what, for convenience of description, may be designated
"London Co-operation." This Metropolitan invention sprang up,
extended, and attracted a pretty good share of attention. Early,
original co-operation, as it is now regarded, is that which was organised
and pursued in Rochdale. This model on which the great stores of the
provinces have been founded has become known as "Rochdale Cooperation."
It may be taken that there are two kinds of Co-operation—Rochdale
Co-operation and London Co-operation. The public generally are not
familiar with the distinction, but it contributes to clearness of view to
apprehend the nature of the two forms and not mistake one for the other.
The Civil Service Supply Association began, the Saturday Review said, with
some members of the Civil Service "who were pinched by low salaries and
high prices"; they combined together for the purpose of obtaining articles
of common domestic use at wholesale prices. They were soon encouraged by
finding that they not only saved a good deal of money, but stood a better
chance of obtaining goods of high quality than when they bought at retail
shops;
but also by learning what great profits the Rochdale, Halifax, and Leeds
Stores had made
in the same way. Thus gentlemen of London were inspired by the artisans
and weavers of Lancashire to establish themselves as shopkeepers. Their humble predecessors had proved
advantages of trading by concert. Thus it dawned upon
the Metropolitan understanding that competition, held up as the
the nursing mother of all social blessings, had not proved itself to be
that self-regulating and provident agency it was supposed to be. Certain
members of
the Civil Service therefore proposed a general revolt of customers in
their body, against London shopkeepers, and devised an association
consisting of
two classes of members—members who were shareholders, and members who
merely held tickets entitling them to make purchases at the stores. Some of the promoters of one association were considered to have acted
with regard to their personal interest, in certain private contracts,
concerning
which the members were not consulted. [195] The general principle professed by
all was co-operative, as far as it went, which was to supply the members
with goods, at wholesale prices, with such addition as left a sufficient
margin for managing expenses. The value of a share at death or withdrawal
was
fixed at 10s.
Shareholders of the C.S.S.A. [196] had prescribed to them the same advantage
as members—namely, that of obtaining good articles at moderate prices
without deriving profit from the transactions carried on in their name. This association soon came to have two places of business, one in the
City, the
other in Long Acre; each being a vast warehouse embracing almost every
description of retail trade. During several years the association
intercepted half
a million of money on its way
to the ordinary shopkeepers' tills. Of course care was taken that the
addition made to the wholesale prices was prudently arranged to leave
sufficient to prevent risk of loss. An excess of profit over working
expenses thus accrued, which left every
year an accumulating sum in the hands of the association. In a few years
this amounted to more than £80,000, when stormy meetings were held to
determine who should have this money. On the whole this association seems
to have been governed by a committee of very honourable gentlemen,
desirous of preventing it descending into a mere trading company, in which
the shareholders make special profits at the
expense of others. The committee were honourably in favour of applying the
great balance in their hands to the reduction in the prices of the
articles, by
which every member would obtain advantages in proportion to his purchases. It was ultimately decided to distribute it among the shareholders, as was
done among the same class in the old co-operative societies of the
Pre-Constructive period.
The Haymarket store was a modest business-looking shop, tame in
appearance, with the Royal Arms over the door, and a small brass plate on
the
entrance, bearing the words "Civil Service Co-operative Society." This is
the principal provision store belonging to an association of gentlemen
from every
branch of the British Civil Service.
This Haymarket store is recorded [197] to have grown out of one commenced by
certain clerks at the General Post Office in 1864. Lowness of salary, and
serious charges on the part of grocers, were alleged as reasons for
forming a combination against them. A strange circular was issued, calling
upon
members of the Civil Service generally to form a Co-operative Society. At
the Post Office there were high officials—Sir Rowland Hill and Mr. W. H. Ashurst,
the solicitor, who were
both acquainted with the history of Co-operation. They were probably not
consulted when it was first thought of, as the project was carried out in
a far
less complete way than persons
so well informed might have advised. Members of the Civil Service
generally did not then know Co-operation from Communism, nor were quite
sure which was which, and the proposal was viewed with
considerable disfavour by the majority of them. Periodicals and
pamphlets, published in
London, had oft told the marvellous story of co-operative profits in the
North of England. Mr. Mill, in his "People's Edition of Political
Economy," had borne
powerful testimony to its significance.
Competition was held to be the parent of all the advantages of the market,
but the excesses of tradesmen's bills were felt to be a great price to pay
for
them, and
eminent members of the Civil Service at length agreed to join in the
revolt against them. Ultimately a board of directors was formed from each
of the
principal departments of the
Crown. It was agreed to commence with a capital of £5,000
in £5 shares, bearing 5 per cent. interest, and no more. This was the
Rochdale amount of shares and limit of interest; a good rule, though
adopted
originally from distrust of
capitalists. The first store was opened near the General Post
office, and limited to members and their families. Purchasing members were
required to pay a fee of 5s. annually for tickets not transferable, giving
the
power of buying at the store. The success of the Post Office Store
extended the spirit of insurgency all over the Service, and a new society
was opened in
the Haymarket, by officials of the higher State Departments, who were
joined in their rebellion by members in every branch of the Service—Home,
Colonial, and Foreign; by peers, members of Parliament, bishops, judges,
colonial governors, foreign consuls, and other high Government officials,
who
had never before regarded Co-operation otherwise than as the ignorant
dream of dangerous visionaries.
The store tea was imported direct from tea-lands. With the purchasing
ticket of the member was handed to the subscriber a book giving a detailed
list of
everything sold at the store itself, with price of each article annexed, a
list of every merchant or tradesman with whom the association had
dealings, and a
catalogue of special articles sold by special tradesmen, advertisements of
merchants on the society's list, and other information of considerable
importance to members of the Civil Service abroad. The society had
physicians, surgeons, accoucheurs, apothecaries, consulting counsel,
solicitors, stockbrokers—all of whom are well known in London as good standing in their
several professions—who engaged to supply the wants of members of the
society at a considerable reduction of their usual charges. The Provident
Clerks' Life Insurance Association had an understanding also with the
society
by which members were insured at lower than ordinary rates. These
operations arose in another London invention, to which, in courtesy, we
may give the
name of Floating Co-operation, which consists in inducing tradesmen to
advertise in some store list of prices, or store journal, and in return
customers
at the store are invited to give their orders to him. The tradesman
further undertakes to make a reduction in his
prices to these customers. In some cases he also gives a commission to
the store upon the orders he thus receives. If a tradesman gets a great
accession of orders by this means, he
can afford to sell as he would to a wholesale purchaser. The
customer, in this case, has no security as to the quality or fairness of his bargain, which a co-operative store affords him. It
is an unpleasant device at the best. If the customers are few, the
tradesman gives them a poor welcome; and if he has two prices for his
goods, he
sometimes tries to discover if the customer has a co-operative ticket upon
him before he names the lower price. The customer has probably heard
that the reduction is often put on before it is taken off, and sometimes
conceals what sort of purchaser he is until he has made his bargain. It
seems a
prostitution of the honest name of Cooperation to apply it to these
furtive Pauline contrivances for economising expenditure by overcoming the
tradesman
"with
guile." The attributes of Co-operation are equity, openness,
and frank consent! None of these qualities are much present
in this system of cheapening by connivance. Imitative Co-operation is
hardly worth more notice than any other expedient by which trade is
diversified
without increasing public morality or amity among purchasers.
These details will give the reader a practical idea of the many sides on
which shopkeepers and professional men were attacked at once. Carriers by
land
and sea, insurance companies, and all orders of men, were made to "stand
and deliver" up some portion of the profits, which, from time immemorial,
had
been theirs. The English excel in insurrection when they once give their
minds to it. Peers, bishops, members of Parliament, and gentlemen, when
they commence it, put the poor and
limited insurgency of working men to shame. Neither Communism nor
Co-operation, in the hands of the people, has ever displayed this
comprehensive
rapacity. No working people ever broke so many ties with their neighbours. No friend of Co-operation wishes to see it advanced this hasty and
embittering way.
The poor are driven by necessity, and oft display an ignorant impatience
of wrong which cannot be rectified at once. They precipitate themselves
into
change, and hope to find it improvement. But from the classes better off,
who have larger means of deliberate action and more intelligence, there is
to be
expected some taste in advancement and that considerateness in progress
which shall make it alluring—raising it from a brutal impetuosity to the
level of
high commerce.
Many a gentleman forsook the shopkeeper between whose family and his own
friendly offices had been interchanged for generations. Peradventure
father
and grandfather before him had been honoured customers at the shop which
he now clandestinely deserted. Had these gentlemen offered cash
payments and given their orders themselves, or sent their wives in their
carriages to do it, as they do at the Haymarket shop, they would have been
served in many cases quite as cheaply, and with more courtesy than at the
store of Imitative Cooperation. Co-operation is the necessity of the poor,
it is
not the necessity of gentlemen. When a shopkeeper cannot supply good
articles, or will not make reasonable charges, or has no special
knowledge of commodities, and pursues shop-keeping as a mere business and
not as an art, customers of taste have no choice but to make a change.
Some gentlemen, who have taken the part of leaders in this revolt of
customers, have been actuated by the conviction that the middleman as an
agent of
distribution is mostly a costly instrument of obsolete commerce. They
admit that where the retail dealer is also the manufacturer of his
commodities,
as in the case of many trades where the shopkeeper sells the productions
of his own handicraft, he will always hold his place. He can guarantee the
goodness of his materials, and his skill and
ingenuity ought to speak for themselves. Where this is the
case, he will attract and keep customers despite all the Co-operation in
the world. He needs no costly shop, customers
will go in search of him anywhere. Work or product of any kind, which has
the character of the artificer in it, will always be sought after so long
as
taste exists or honesty is valued. The mere middleman who has special
knowledge of the nature of the articles or commodities in which he deals,
and
who has a character for honestly describing them, and of charging
reasonably for goods to which his discernment and attestation value, will
always hold
his place and command respect. Put the class of mere mechanical middlemen
and shopkeepers who do not know, and do not care, what they offer you,
provided they can induce you to buy it, or who conspire to keep up prices
by preventing the customer from finding any better article in the market,
are
mere parasites of trade, whom Co-operation serves society by sweeping away.
London Co-operation, as represented by Civil Service or Army and Navy
Stores, has only the merit of saving somewhat the pockets of their
customers,
without affording them the facility and inducement to acquire the habit of
saving, which is needed as much by the middle class as by the poor. These
societies, organised chiefly to supply goods at a cheap rate, and make a
large profit for the shareholders, are not co-operative in the complete
sense of
that term, since the managers have an interest distinct from the
shareholders, and the shareholders an interest distinct from the
purchasers. The
managers are not known to care for Co-operation as a system of equity and
honesty, and are not under the supervision of directors elected by the
purchasers, and charged with the duty of carrying out the principle of
Co-operation. Civil Service Stores, or Military Service Stores, and
similar
associations, are virtually private commercial societies bent upon
realising the economy of combination without caring much about the
morality of it. They
do not intend to disregard morality any more than other commercial firms,
but leave it to take care
of itself and, peradventure, hope it will come all right. The managers
generally have in view the highest remuneration they can obtain for
themselves
compatible with keeping the shareholders in a contented state of mind with
regard to their
dividend. The shareholders in their turn are chiefly solicitous
to see that purchasers have goods of such quality and at such prices as
shall secure their custom. But whether the quality as pure as it should
be, or the
prices as low as they might be,
is not considerations which they have any interest in entertaining.
These associations do not proceed so much upon the principle of equity as
upon doing business. The common principle of managers, shareholders, and
purchasers is that of
all competitive commerce—each for himself and the devil take the hindmost; and such is the activity of the devil in business, that he commonly does
it.
Co-operation, on the other hand, is a concerted arrangement for keeping
the devil out of the
affair. A scheme of equity has no foremost and no hindmost
for the devil to take. Everybody in the society stands in a circle, and
the total profits made are distributed equitably all round the
circumference.
"London Co-operation" begins in distrust of the shopkeeper, and ends with
obtaining, at considerable personal trouble, a reduction of a shilling in
the
pound at the store counter; and if the purchaser can obtain the same
reduction at the grocer's shop, and the goods are equally satisfactory,
there is no
reason why he should not return to the shop and abandon the store. "London Co-operation" which most stirs the terrors of shopkeepers has
small hold
upon the interest or respect of its customers, beyond that which accrues
from
saving them a shilling in the pound. Under this cold and covetous plan the
mighty phalanx of great stores throughout
the country would never have existed. All the public would ever have seen
would be a solitary big grocer's shop here and there, mentioned, perhaps,
by
some commercial traveller in the commercial-room at night, but neither
Parliament nor history
would have heard of Co-operation. The great movement has grown in strength
and in public interest by capitalising the savings of the customers.
By Co-operation stores create a new system of distribution; by productive
societies, where profit is shared with labour, it aims at changing the
character
of industry by substituting self-employment for hired labour.
Imitative Co-operation, so far as it may assist the incomes of some
struggling middle-class persons, poorly-paid civil servants, law, and
mercantile clerks,
is an advantage. In so far as these shadowy stores call the attention of
the more
influential classes to Co-operation, and interest them in it, and induce
them to countenance the co-operative principle, they do good and are part
of the
general propagandism of the idea of economy by concert. Such praise as
belongs to this order of service I ungrudgingly give, but there is no use
in
making more of anything than there is in it; and if a scheme is good as
far as it goes but falls short of what it should be, and fails to do the
good it ought,
that should be made clear in the interest of progress.
Thus there are two kinds of stores, the market-price charging and saving
stores, and the Civil Service under-selling and unsaving stores. The
market-price and saving store belongs to real Co-operation, which is a
device for the improvement of the condition of the poor. In the provinces
the sort of
supply association which the Civil Service stores have brought into
imitative existence are often mere schemes of gentlemen at large, for
intercepting the
profits of tradesmen, for the benefit of shareholders and persons of
position, who
turn amateur huxters for a pecuniary consideration. Among the "patrons" or
"directors" whose names are published there is scarcely one familiar
to the co-operative ears. They know nothing of Co-operation—possibly care
nothing for it. They cannot explain its principles nor advocate them, nor
vindicate them. In its struggles they have taken no part, nor rendered any
aid. In its difficulties they have given it no encouragement, nor made any
sacrifices to support it. In the
days when adversaries abounded, they stood aloof. When Co-operation has
been regarded with odium they disowned it. In all its literature, their
speeches or writings in its defence are nowhere to be found. When Acts of
Parliament had to be obtained, at the infinite labour and cost of years
of agitation, they took no part, and gave no thought, or time, or trouble
to conquer the reluctance of the House of Commons for facilitating the
formation of
societies, or concede them legal protection.
There is no reason, of course, why those who did not do what they ought,
or what they might, should not be applauded for doing what they did in the
right
direction. A co-operative society proper divides whatever savings it makes
among all its customers who buy from it, and employees, who
can do so much for its interest; an Imitative Co-operation merely gives
partial reduction in price to the purchaser, and awards the remainder as
personal
profit to managers or directors, to promoters or patrons.
An original co-operative store permanently increases the means of the
poor, by saving their profits for them and teaching them the art of
thrift. An imitative
store does nothing more than cultivate the love of cheapness without
providing security that the cheapness is real.
An original store, by augmenting the means of humble purchasers, prevents
them becoming a burden upon the poor rates and a tax upon shopkeepers.
An imitative store renders little service to the indigent, and by
abstracting the custom of the tradesman, reduces his means of paying the
poor-rates which
fall upon him.
At the same time since the better class of London stores have stopped
credit purchases, and enabled the public to obtain articles at a lower
rate than
otherwise they could obtain them, they have raised the expectation that
the articles they supply can be depended upon to be good of their kind,
and to
raise this expectation is useful, as it imposes a certain obligation of
meeting it, and so far as the London stores accomplish these things, they
may claim
credit for usefulness, and are to be regarded for the merit they have. As
copyists of Co-operation they are entitled to "honourable
mention" according to their skill.
It would be no more fair in commerce than in literature to judge any one
by some other standard than that which he has set before himself. A critic
ofttimes condemns an author because his book does not come up to some
ideal in the critic's mind of what such a book ought to be. This is not
criticism, it is dogmatism. A writer, or a social contriver, is not to be
condemned for falling below a model which he never proposed to imitate. If
the
model he has chosen is a poor one or an unworthy one, it is plainly useful
to say so, that
nobler attempts may be incited in him or others. A trader in ideas or
commodities is to be estimated mainly by the good sells, and good services
to be
found in the work he actually does. The leading aim of Co-operation is not
merely to increase present comfort (albeit not a disagreeable thing to
do),
it seeks also to ensure competence. Those who do not provide for the
future of themselves and families, as far as they call—or far as they
ought [198] are
not merely dependent, they are mean, since they leave to chance, or the
charity of others, to provide for them when the evil day comes. The middle
and
upper classes are not much better than the working classes in these
respects. Noblemen quarter their families on the State, and
a
Conservative Government (unless it is much misjudged) is always ready to
find them facilities to that end, in the ecclesiastical, military, and
maritime
departments, and by keeping in their hands the school endowments of the
poor. Noblemen have no general reputation for paying their debts when due.
Industry is considered a plebeian pursuit, and the middle class ape a
gentility of indebtedness which their creditors are far from approving.
In a society on the Rochdale plan the profit due to the purchaser is, by
arrangement, saved for him. The society becomes to him a Savings Bank. He
finds
himself surrounded by members and neighbours who have £20, £50, £100, and
some £200 in the society, intending to invest it in buying a house, or
investing it in some co-operative quarry, or mine, or manufactory.
In what is called "London Co-operation," as represented by Civil Service
and similar societies, no facility of saving in the way we have described
is
afforded, though in thousands of families of the middle class, and indeed
in many of those of the wealthier classes, the facility would be as
valuable as in
the households of working people. In co-operative families, when the
father or mother begins to save in this way, the example spreads through
the house.
The young people learn to save. They see the advantage of possessing money
of their own, at their own control, and acquire a spirit of wholesome
independence because they owe everything to themselves. This saving costs
them no privation; they lose no comfort to effect their accumulations. They
have simply to make all their small purchases at a store, and the small
profits they would distribute among the shopkeepers about them come at the
end of the quarter into their own pockets. Sometimes these young
persuade their friends, who do not belong themselves to any any store, to
let them make their purchases for themselves.
These purchases, entrusted to these minor co-operators, cost nothing to
those who give them, and the youthful commissioners learn thrift and gain
by the
opportunity, and become little millionaires in their own estimation.
In co-operative families the sons and daughters commonly become members on
their own account. The young men learn other economies, avoiding
needless and wasteful pleasures which they would never otherwise avoid,
and are the better in their habits and health in consequence; and when
the
time for setting up households of their own arrives, they often have a
house of their own to go into. It is found that young women are often as
clever as
their brothers in saving, when their minds are well put in the way of it. Many a girl has found herself sought for in marriage by a better class of
suitor than
would ever have fallen in her way, had it not been discovered that she had
a fund of her own in the co-operative store. The certainty that a prudent
girl will
make a prudent wife, and be the mistress of a prudent household, is a
popular belief which acts as an unsolicited letter of recommendation to
her. If it can
be shown that persons can save without laying anything by, accumulate
money without paying anything out of their pocket, and save without living
any
way poorer, or meaner than they did, this were surely to make saving easy,
alluring, and inevitable. This is the moral, social, and salutary
discovery which
co-operative societies have made. Future advantage seems to most persons a
poor thing compared with present satisfaction. Many only half believe in
the need of a future day, which comes as surely as death; and
often they both come together. A co-operative store dispenses with this
scant, difficult, and precarious heroism of daily life, without requiring
the
strength of mind which looks the future
in the face, and provides for it. A co-operative store offers means
of saving without effort. No homily, no precept, no wise saw, or modern
instance, no exhortation, or prayer, or entreaty, inspire strength of will
or
wise and lasting purpose in the average mind of any class, like facility
alone brought to their
doors, put into their hands, saving made part of the very convenience of
their daily life, which Co-operation furnishes, effects the change from
thoughtlessness to thrift, as no other human device has ever been found to
do. [199]
The press is at times as confusing as the pulpit. [200] Surely it is idle to
say (as other political economists as eminent as Professor Hodgson have
said) that if
a man saves 2s. in the pound in a purchase it makes no difference to him
whether he receives the money weekly or at the end of the quarter; he has
the
money in his pocket, and if he wants to save it he can do so. This is a
mad theory of human conduct, as it implies that all men are perfect, that
all minds
are prudent, and bent upon prudence always; that the advantages and fine
spirit of self-providence is present to the mind of every one, and present
unintermittingly. It implies that opportunity of some gratification, which
betrays nine out of every ten, every wakeful hour of their lives, can be
set aside and
disregarded at will. It implies that omnipresent strength of purpose which
the philosopher extols as the perfection of character, which he never
expects to
see prevalent; which no Utopian ever dreams will be universal—is to be
found in every one, and found always. If men could be trusted to save
because
they have the means of doing so, insurance societies would be
impertinencies, since every man could more or less provide for himself if he took care of his means when he has them. All the laws and all the
devices of social life, to protect the thoughtless from themselves, and to
prevent
temptation from destroying the
foolish or the weak, would be unnecessary. Thus the compulsory thrift
of Co-operation is one of the most necessary and beneficent features of
that wise self-helping scheme.
Cobden held the theory that nothing would be so popular as a newspaper
distinguished for furnishing facts. No paper ever lived long enough to
succeed in
this adventurous department. The cost of getting at facts is enormous. They are
as scarce as gold. The most valuable facts commonly lie very low down, and
are as uncertain to find, and costly to get at, as
boring for coal in an unexplored field. So difficult are they to find that
men are celebrated as discoverers who first produce facts in art, or
politics; in
science, or social life; and when found it requires a man of genius to
identify them and interpret
them. Ordinary people do not know what to do with them. In a West End
district in London, where needy or thoughtless people are not expected to
abound, there is a pawnbroker's shop where 2,000 pledges are redeemed
every Saturday night
and 400 new pledges are brought in. Pawnbrokers' shops are the humble
banks of the poor, who, when sudden sickness or distress overtakes them,
or a journey has to be made to a dying child or parent, indigent women can
there obtain a little money when they have no friend to lend them any, and
only
possess some wearing apparel, or wedding ring, which they can give
up in exchange for money. These cases, however, represent a very small
portion of that great crowd whose folly, or vice, or improvidence make up
the
2,400 applicants who, in one night, throng the pawnbroker's shop we have
indicated. What an ignominious crowd to contemplate! Two or three
co-operative stores in that neighbourhood would do more to thin the
deplorable throng than all the moralists, philosophers, professors of
political
economy, and preachers London could furnish. These stores ought to be
promulgated by missionary zeal, and men might give themselves to the work,
as to a great religious duty.
If gentlemen had taken to co-operative trading with a view to elevate it,
and improve shop-keeping by improving the taste of purchasers, by the
gradual
introduction of becoming colours and qualities, and articles of honest
manufacture, no words of honour would be too strong to apply to such
amateur
shopkeepers. Some years ago I made an appeal [201] to the piety of London to
do something practical in the name of faith. A few congregations in every
district of the far-extending metropolis might unite in setting up a
good co-operative store. If deacons, elders, lady visitors, and
local missionaries were to visit the poor of the neighbourhood with half
as much interest in the
welfare of their bodies as that they display for the health their souls,
they would soon have thousands of poor members at
their co-operative store. If they saved the profits of the poor for them, and
encouraged them to permit the slow accumulation, they would teach them
in
time the holy art of thrift and independence. If the wealthy members chose to deal at the stores and save
their profits, not for the baser reason of adding already sufficient
gains,
but for the purpose of devoting them works of art, or to that charity
which helps the unfortunate and does not make mendicants, they might do good
with dignity, and do it without cost.
CHAPTER XXVI.
METROPOLITAN PROPAGANDISM
"I regard social schemes as one of the most valuable
elements of human improvement."—JOHN
STUART MILL,
Political Economy.
LONDON has started more co-operative societies and
projects than any city ten times told. If it has not succeeded with them,
it has enabled
others to do so. It may be held that it
has had real co-operative enthusiasm and enterprise. Somebody must go
forward with an ideal, which the "practical" people carry out, but
rarely
have the capacity to discover for themselves; and when they succeed, they
are apt to disparage the thinkers who inspired them.
The vicissitudes of Co-operation in the metropolis would be an instructive
narrative in itself. In several parts of England societies formed in the
Pioneer
period, and before it, continue to exist. In London no society formed in
those days has
continued. There was an intermittent platform advocacy of it at the old
Hall of Science, City Road (rented mainly by Mr. Mordan, of gold-pen
repute, for Mr. Rowland Detroiser to lecture in), when physical science
really was taught there; and industrial advocacy was continuous and
incessant on
the platform at the John Street Institution, Tottenham Court Road, and at
the Cleveland Hall, hard by, for a time. Indeed, in every hall—in Theobald's Road,
Gray's Inn Road, in Goswell Road, Islington
Whitechapel, Hackney, Blackfriars Road, in the Rotunda in the days of
Carlile, Queen Street, Charlotte Street, at Castle Street, Oxford Street,
and
subsequently at the new Hall of Science, in Old Street, St. Luke's, and in every Free
Thought or Secular Hall which has been occupied in the
metropolis—co-operative advocacy has more or less been heard.
It was in London that the "British Association for the
Diffusion of Co-operative Knowledge" was formed. It is the tendency
of the metropolis to think more of disseminating true ideas than to profit
by them. The tone of the metropolitan mind is imperial.
Thinkers strive to act from London upon the empire. The best ideas
do not often originate in London but they receive a welcome there.
Through the kindness of Dr. Yeats there has come to my hands "The Report
of the Committee appointed by a Meeting of Journeymen, chiefly Printers,"
to consider the first systematic plan of Co-operation known to have been
proposed. The plan was that of Mr. George Mudie. The second
edition of the Report is dated January 23, 1821. The Report first
appeared in 1820, and it speaks of having been long under consideration,
so that as early as 1818 or 1819 Co-operation, as a "plan of arrangement"
for working people, was formally put forth. Mr. Mudie is spoken of
as having delivered discourses thereupon in the metropolis. Mr.
Mudie's scheme was that of a community of goods; but the Committee
proposed to adapt its co-operative features to friendly societies and
working-men's clubs, which was done in 1821, and was the beginning of
co-operative societies in London. The Report was signed by Robert
Hunt, James Shallard, John Jones, George Hinde, Robert Dean, and Henry
Hetherington. The Report is the ablest, least sentimental, the most
clearly written and exhaustive—touching community schemes and
co-operative application—I have met with in the early literature of the
movement.
One passage, which expresses the first conception formed of
that practical Co-operation which we now know, will enable the reader to
judge this remarkable Report "It appears to us that the principle of
Co-operation is susceptible of many modifications. In some cases its
benefits could only be partially obtained. Wherever Friendly
Societies or Benefit Clubs exist, the members would do well to form
themselves into associations for reaping the advantages of this plan.
In some cases it might be merely practicable to unite a portion of their
earnings, for the purchase in the best markets, of certain articles of
provision or clothing; while in other cases where the parties inhabit
contiguous dwellings, some of the advantages resulting from the
subdivision of domestic labour might also be secured, and erections
adapted for the purposes of cooking and washing be made at the back of one
or more of the dwellings at a small expense. [202]
If men can be brought seriously and earnestly to consider how they can
unite their talents, experiences, and pecuniary resources to attain
advantages in which each should equitably participate, they will assuredly
succeed in improving their condition; and if by any economical
arrangements the earnings of individuals in question can be made to
produce a greater quantity of articles of consumption than is to be
obtained on the plan of each individual catering for his own family, the
effect will be the same as would follow an increase of wages or a decrease
of taxes."
The Home Colonisation Society, of which Mr. William Galpin
was the chief promoter, and to which Mr. Frederick Bate was the chief
subscriber, was formed in London twenty years later, 1840-1. The
first Central Board of the Society had offices in the metropolis for some
years in Bloomsbury Square, and the New Moral World was printed by
Ostell, round the corner in Hart Street.
The Christian Socialists of London took the field on behalf
of Co-operation, 1848-9. The higher aims they put before and kept
before co-operators [203] have
made their influence the most fortunate which has befallen the movement.
It was in Charlotte Street, which Mr. Owen had previously made famous,
that the barristers' and clergymen's co-operative movement commenced, the
said Christian Socialist Organisation of a Central Co-operative Agency and
Working Men's Associations. Having fortune, learning, and influence,
they attracted important attention to the subject, and issued publications
explanatory of their intentions. With generosity and zeal and at
great cost, the work was conducted.
From 1850 to 1855 attempts were made in London to establish a
Wholesale Supply Association, under the name of the Universal Purveyor,
for the manufacture, preparation, and sale of food, drinks, and drugs,
guaranteed against adulteration and fraud, and just in purity, quality,
weight, measure, and price. The commencing capital was £10,000 in
1,000 shares of £10. The project lasted in force but a few years.
M. Jules le Chevalier St. Andre, formerly a St. Simonian enthusiast, but
not at all an enthusiast in London, but a very obese and accomplished
projector, was concerned in both these schemes. The chief supporter
of the Purveyor was the Rev. C. Marriott, who at that time was Dean of
Oriel, Oxford. He was certainly a clergyman of great
disinterestedness, who ran great pecuniary risks, and incurred several
losses to serve others. M. St. Andre had a masterly way of putting a
case which would interest a clergyman like Charles Marriott. It was
not until after much money had been lost in Charlotte Street, Fitzroy
Square, and the business there was ended, that M. St. Andre commenced his
"Universal Purveyor" at 23, King William Street. In one of his last
circulars he said, "The most obstructive difficulty was inherent to the
state of the English law, whereby it was not possible to take part in any
enterprise, admitting of some risk, without being entrapped, as it were,
into unlimited responsibility. The unalterable faith in God,
which has supported me through all the apparent hopelessness of a
righteous cause, strengthens in me every day more and more the belief that
by coming forward personally as trustee, and financially with every means
he could place at my disposal, the Rev. C. Marriott has laid the
foundation of an institution pregnant of important results. The Rev.
C. Marriott was perfectly aware that as a trustee he would have been made
responsible with us. But there was no other means of doing what he
thought his duty, and he did it. Thank God, he has come out safe,
after enabling us to reach the time when the principle of limited
liability has been introduced in the English law."
All that relates to Mr. Marriott was true and most honourable
to him. What it cost him to "come out safe" is not stated.
Gentlemen more experienced in the world, and more in it than Mr. Marriott,
had found that "an unalterable trust in God," while very well in its
place, may be very costly in business, unless accompanied by secular
qualifications. St. Andre well knew this, and also understood what a
Wholesale Agency should be, and his description of it is worth preserving.
Its conditions were these:—
1. An extent of operations embracing the supply of all
articles for domestic consumption. 2. Making the guarantee of
purity, quality, quantity, and fair price the special duty and
responsibility of the establishment. 3. Selling on commission only,
and not making any speculative profits. 4. Extensive warehouses for
examining and testing the goods before packing and delivery. 5. The
most perfect machinery for weighing, packing, and labelling large
quantities of parcels of every description. 6. Organisation of a
Commission of Referees, composed of professional men of the highest
standing. 7. Appointed buyers, morally responsible to the public.
8. A strong body of respectable servants as clerks, travellers, packers,
warehousemen, pledged to certain modes of dealing, thoroughly impressed
with the fact that they are on public duty. [204]
Years after the disappearance of the Working Men's
Associations founded by the Christian Socialists, I and Mr. E. R. Edger
held meetings at "The Raglan" (Mr. Jagger's coffeehouse), 71, Theobald's
Road. The object of these meetings was to suggest a plan of combined
action for all the London stores, and to invite their co-operation in
circulating an address to the people with the object of increasing the
members and custom of every store. There were then some twenty or
thirty stores in London, scattered and isolated. Mr. Ebenezer Edger,
Mr. E. O. Greening, and I published the Social Economist, 1868, for
the purpose of promoting organisation among these stores; Mr. Edger wrote
a wise series of tracts for circulation among the members. By the
generous aid of a munificent friend of Co-operation—always nameless, but
incessant in service—Mr. Greening and I continued, in London, the
Social Economist, which for a considerable period sought to inform
co-operators of the nature of Continental thought, as respects the
organisation of social life and labour. It was subsequently discontinued
on behalf of the Co-operative News, that there might be unity and greater
interest in the new journal then projected. A "London Association for the
Promotion of Co-operation" was in operation in 1863. Mr. J. S. Mill, Professsor F. W. Newman, and Mr. E. Vansittart Neale permitted their names
to be announced as honorary members. The committee was composed of
officers of these existing co-operative societies. It was stated by this
body that there were at that time "forty societies in London and its
vicinity."
The establishment of the Agricultural and Horticultural Co-operative
Association in London devised by Mr. Edward Owen Greening, Mr. Walter
Morrison, M.P., Thorns Hughes, M.P., and the Hon. Mr. Cowper-Temple, M.P.,
other gentlemen being directors, gave practical Co-operation position in
the metropolis. The progress of this association is as remarkable as that
of any society extant, considering that it occupied an entirely new field,
and sought members among the farmers of England, who do not take readily
to new ideas. Mr. E. O. Greening, the manager, being possessed of real
co-operative knowledge, skilled in devising new applications of it, and of
zeal and capacity in advocacy, exercised considerable
propagandist influence in London. This Agricultural Association has
maintained a standard of co-operative principle which has been effective
upon the Civil Service societies in some instances. Mr. Greening and
others caused the formation of a Co-operative Institute in Castle Street,
in a large building formerly the Concert Room of the Princess's Theatre,
Oxford
Street. The names of Thomas Brassey, M.P., the Earl of Rosebery, and
Arthur Trevelyan appear among the promoters, in addition to other
well-known friends of industrial endeavour, as Walter Morrison, Charles
Morrison, and the Right Hon. Cowper-Temple, M.P. The Daily News gave a
comprehensive account of it, saying: "This Co-operative Institute is
not, as might be inferred from the name, a trading company, but a society
formed to organise the means of pure and elevating enjoyment, members'
subscriptions being applied to educational or recreative purposes. . . . It provides the advantages or lectures, concerts, the use of Mudie's
books, a reading-room, and, as far as possible, the usual adjuncts of a
club. There are occasionally social evenings for dancing, but no
intoxicants are permitted, and admission is limited to members." The
Central Co-operative Board and some societies made subscriptions to it.
A Central Co-operative Agency Society, Limited, was established in London
for the sale of co-operative manufactures
and provisions, wholesale and retail. An excellent thing is at times set
going, but few devote themselves to seeing it go and taking care that it
does go.
The Agricultural Association built a council-room in Millbrook Street; the
Central Board of the Southern Section sat there and devised a Metropolitan
Co-operative Society, one object being to open stores in suitable
districts. These stores were to be supplied with provisions from the
Manchester Wholesale. So comprehensive a scheme was impossible
before the Branch of the Manchester Wholesale was opened at 118, Minories,
now 99, Leman Street, London. Mr. William Openshaw is now the manager.
Since 1875 the proceedings of the Annual Congress have been regulated by
the laws of a Co-operative Union adopted at the London Congress in that
year. This Union prescribes the conditions under which societies may
become members of it, and send delegates to it. It appoints a Central
Board which officially governs the proceedings of the united co-operative
body. Sectional Boards meet in various districts. Delegates from each of
these Boards meet periodically in Manchester to transact the general
business of the Union under the name of the United Board.
"This Union is formed to promote the practice of truthfulness, justice,
and economy in production and exchange
"(1) By the abolition of all false dealing, either—
"a. Direct, by representing any article produced or sold to be other than
what it is known to the producer or vendor to be; or
"b. Indirect, by concealing from the purchaser any fact known to the
vendor material to be known by the purchaser, to enable him to judge of
the value of the article purchased.
"(2) By conciliating the conflicting interests of the capitalist, the
worker, and the purchaser, through an equitable division among them of the
fund commonly known as Profit.
"(3) By preventing the waste of labour, now caused by unregulated
competition.
"[The Union does not affect to determine precisely what division of this
fund shall be considered equitable, believing that this is a question
admitting of different solutions, under different
circumstances, and not to be concluded by any hard-and-fast line. But it
insists on the recognition of the principle.]"
Mr. Hodgson Pratt, a ceaseless worker for social
improvement, not merely
doing with zeal what routine work may come before him in the movements he
assists, but assiduously devising new methods of advancing
the objects in in view, projected a Co-operative Guild for
the purpose of creating organised propagandism of principles of Industrial
Association. At the Glasgow Congress of 1876 it was first agreed to
form a Guild on the plan of the ancient societies of that name. It was proposed
by myself to give effect to a striking paper on Propagandism read by Mr.
Joseph Smith, secretary to the Manchester Board. The draft of the Guild
was signed by G. J. Holyoake, A. Greenwood, W. Nuttall, J, Smith, E. V. Neale, J. Crabtree, J. M. Percival, H. J. Wiley.
This "Guild of Co-operative Pioneers" was intended to comprise a Master
of the Guild, and (1) Associates
examined in Co-operative Principle; (2) Companions examined in Methods of
Co-operative Procedure; (3) Administrators examined in the Government of
Societies; (4) Members examined in policy and debate in Societies and
Congress. The object of this Guild was to train a body of persons in every
town who should possess usefulness and authority, by reason of their known
devotion and ascertained qualifications.
Mr. Hodgson Pratt's scheme was originated quite independently. It
commenced in March, 1878, after a series of four lectures in Exeter Hall;
the first being delivered by Thomas Hughes, Q.C., on the History of
Co-operation, Mr. Hodgson Pratt presiding.
Spurious Co-operation became a fashion in London with pretended "Co-operative Shops." A single adventure, multiplied himself into a Firm,
and announced himself as a
"Co-operative Company." Fictitious "Co-operative Banks" made their
appearance. Mr. Richard Banner Oakley failed in many attempts to get the
Congress to recognise him, or the Central Board, or the Co-operative News
to countenance his operations. No store ever had dealings with him. The
outside public, from treating Co-operation with ignorant distrust, at last
believed in it with an ignorant credulity. When he invented his
Co-operative Credit Bank, papers spoke of it as an instance of
"Co-operative credulity," whereas
the co-operators were the only persons who had no faith in it.
There was a Co-operative Coal Society in Chancery Lane, London, managed by
Mr. Julius Forster. Deficiency of fuel means increased contagion,
premature death to the old, and privation in many ways. To help to avert
this, in the days of the coal famine, the Co-operative Coal Supply
Association held a Conference in Millbank Street Hall, to promote
co-operative coal-mining. In the North of England the working miners had
then taken some coal royalties, and, with secured orders from London, they
could work them with profit.
The Manchester Co-operative Fire Insurance Society (which has shown a
growing prosperity for years), of which Mr. James Odgers is secretary, has
its head office in Long Millgate, Manchester. This Society, commenced in
1872, also issues Guarantees of Fidelity of Servants of Co-operative
Societies. It has also a Life Department.
It is one of the pleas for the inability of London to co-operate that the
population is transitory. Still householders remain pretty constant. Population, which seems fluctuating under facilities of transit and
emigration, resembles the deposits at a bank. Though withdrawable on
demand a profitable proportion of money always remains on hand. It is the
same with workmen. Great numbers expect to live in the place in which they
were born or have settled; as witness the statements made at the meeting
of "The British Association" [205] at Bradford in 1873, that the following
building societies, [206] composed mainly of working people, had these
members and income in 1872;
Title of Society |
Members |
Funds (£) |
Bradford
Second Equitable |
6,277 |
265,000 |
Bradford
Third Equitable |
7,200 |
537,000 |
Leeds
Permanent |
12,020 |
365,000 |
Leeds
Provincial |
5,250 |
200,000 |
Halifax
Permanent |
6,167 |
174,000 |
These masses of membership do not look like population. If as much
interest was taken in co-operative as in religious propagandism, and a
hundred members of any congregation were to guarantee to buy not less
than £1 worth of goods weekly from its store, the storekeepers might
undertake to contribute £1,000 every four years to the income of the
Church.
CHAPTER XXVII.
SOCIAL POLICY OF CO-OPERATIVE SOCIETIES
"He neither power nor places
sought,
For others not himself he fought.
He might have been a king,
But that he understood
How much it was a meaner thing
To be unjustly great--than honourably good."
The Duke of Buckingham's Epitaph on Lord
Fairfax |
THE noblest scheme of liberty or set of rules in the
world will be dead letters unless men with a passion for the right carry
them out. The right men are known by the policy they pursue.
Some men profess not to know what policy is. Yet they know that if a
man wishes to appear superior to his neighbours without trouble, his
policy is not to work. If his intention is not to work, his policy
is to live by borrowing as less dangerous but not less dishonest than
stealing. But if a man intends to live by industry and to get on by
good sense, he adopts certain rules of probity and usefulness, and
integrity and service constitute his policy.
Co-operation implies a training in the unknown art of
association. The earlier advocates of industrial equity had
everything to learn, and to fight their way step by step in the shop, in
the market, on the platform, and in the press. The instructed seldom
befriended them, and adversaries never gave them quarter. In this
solitary contention they discovered some facts of the policy of success.
1. Never to conceal what ought, in business, honestly
to be made known, nor communicate to assailants outside business, what is
no business of theirs.
Catlin tells us that the astute American Indian always keeps
his mouth shut, until he has some purpose in opening it; and the Indian
mother watches her boy while he sleeps, carefully closing his lips, if
apart, that he may acquire the habit of keeping them shut night and day,
as audible breathing may one day betray him in his lair. There are
men in movement who always have their mouths open. It may be owing
to mere labial deficiency, or to their having had parents who knew nothing
of the importance of educated habit; but to the spectator it seems a sign
of vacuity or foolishness. Some of the early Socialists had this
peculiarity, not from physical but intellectual deficiency in the power of
reticence. Speech escaped from them without calculation of its
relevancy or use. Co-operation still suffers from a suicidal
publicity. If some rival firm refuses to sell to them provisions or
materials they go to the expense of printing a circular about it, or put
it in a paper and circulate the fact that they are disabled from carrying
on their business. They thus cause adversaries to combine against
them, and then squeal out when the pressure is put upon them, although
they inform their own connection that they are disabled; thus they
minister to the personal triumph as well as business success of their
clever and reticent adversaries, who know better how to close their mouths
and work in the shade. Co-operators know that competition is a
battle in which there are few scruples and no quarter, and yet many of
them chatter as though it was a tea-party. It is the same in
Radicalism, where publicity is a disease instead of a purpose. It is
the malady of inexperience. Conservative working men are as bad when
they are allowed to speak. What matters it to co-operators if the
enemy close the markets where they must purchase provisions to distribute,
or materials with which to conduct productive manufactures? This can
be overcome in commerce and trade by establishing wholesale societies, and
entering the markets with means of making large purchases.
Theological alarm is far more implacable than that of business.
Defamation is conveyed down a thousand devious lines of prejudice, where
stately and friendless truth is too proud, too scornful, or too poor to
follow it; and there it lives till Time starves it, or the contempt of a
second and better-instructed generation kills it.
2. The co-operator makes no proclamation as to his
religious opinions, and treats any demand of the kind as a social outrage.
Religion, in the sense of reverence for truth, is confined to a few
persons in every generation. With this religion of the understanding
Co-operation is wholly coincident. The most human parts of the Bible
are those which express sympathy for the poor. Co-operation respects
this sympathy, but objects to being poor, and holds that there is neither
need, nor use, nor good in being poor. When a man discovers that the
established measurement of truth is wrong, and announces one more
accurate, men put him down as being no better than he should be, which
merely means that he is nearer to the reality of things than his
neighbours.
3. Self-helping in all things, the co-operator
chooses his own principles, and answers for them himself. The poorer
sort of persons with new ideas are eager to have them discussed. It
is their only chance of getting attention. To accomplish this they
must uphold the principle of free discussion. Yet discussion once
sanctioned in any party, all sorts of questions are raised, and the
responsibility of the opinions advanced is, in a manner, diffused over the
whole party who uphold the principle. Hence Co-operation, in its
early days, was charged with complicity with every utopianism of the hour,
discussed in its halls, or advocated by its supporters. Of course
this mistake would not be made about it, if the public discriminated; but
the public is a creature which never does discriminate. Not only do
co-operators suffer from misconception, but philosophers suffer from it.
John Stuart Mill was a memorable instance of this; because he wrote
letters on behalf, or on some occasions gave support to, persons whose
views the public did not like, it was assumed that Mr. Mill did like them.
This did not by any means follow. Mr. Mill believed that progress
needed to be promoted, and that it was retarded by persons not saying what
they thought right, and by not acting upon it when they had said it.
He therefore encouraged this being done, without at all agreeing with the
particular views of each individual, or his mode of carrying them out.
The men who inspired the co-operative movement, who believed
in it when no one else did, whose intrepidity and persistence have been
the cause of its success, were men who held no second-hand opinions, but
debated out for themselves what they sought to know, and had to depend
upon. So vigilant were they that they never suffered any speaker to
address an audience in their name, unless he submitted what he said to
criticism and opportunity of refutation. They regarded as a deceiver
or a traitor any who sought to impose pose upon them opinions he did not
invite them to verify and enable them to do it.
4. To regard every member as actuated by
veracity and right intentions, and in case of difference of opinion to
reason with them as being in error--not as being base. So solicitous
were the early co-operators for neutrality in imputation that they
prohibited all praise or blame, in order that the mind being kept
passionless, might move in the equable plane of simple truth.
Certainly no signs of approval or disapproval kept a speaker quiet, but it
made him dull. He never knew whether he was a fool or a wit.
He might as well have addressed so many bales of cotton, as a neutral
audience of social improvers of this way of thinking. Other and
wiser exactions were made. Whoever spoke among them was forbidden to
be imputative. He was told to pity the vituperative assailant (to
whom neither Nature nor culture had given sense or taste) not to imitate
him. Thirty years before Mr. Matthew Arnold pointed out that Paul,
when he called his adversaries "dogs" and "vain babblers," had no chance
of convincing them, nor had Christ any chance of gaining the Scribes and
Pharisees by the invectives he launched at them when he abandoned his
mild, uncontentious, winning mode of working. "He shall not
strive or cry" was his true characteristic, in which all his charm and
power lay. Thirty years ere this was said co-operators were taught
consideration in speech, and it was known among them that denunciation of
persons was the cheapest, easiest, most popular, and most unwholesome use
to which the human tongue could be put, and that the wanton imputation of
evil motives to others was an abuse of free speech. Defamation of
motives assume an infallibility of discernment which no man is endowed
with, and denotes utter ignorance of the duty of exposition and of the art
of persuading the minds of men. Those who seek the truth, and care
for the truth, are traitors to it when they employ unfairness of terms.
He who is imputative and unjust of speech, turns men from him for ever,
and is not long credited himself with purity of motive. So sharply
should consequence be connected with conduct, that a brutal sincerity
should be held as much a betrayal of the truth as the denial of it; for he
who denies it merely hides it, while he who makes it offensive makes it to
be hated. The moment an unjust imputation is made ill-feeling
begins, and the wisdom or error of any step is at once lost sight of.
The moment personalities are permitted, the tongue of every fool is
loosened, and floods of resentment and rancour drown all argument and
arrest all concert.
Mr. John Holmes, who has published some wise conditions of
co-operative success, errs in one where he prescribes, "Forbearance
towards each other's disinterested opinions." Now
co-operators have nothing to do with the question whether the opinions of
their colleagues are interested or "disinterested," but simply with
the truth and value of their opinions. Any question as to the
motives or "disinterestedness" of the opinions is the beginning of
disunion and of imputation, which kills concord.
A hearty geniality is of great value in co-operative
societies. A business watchfulness which never sleeps, and a
pleasantry of manner which never fails, are qualities above all value in a
co-operator in office. His smile is a public gift, the tone of his
voice is an act of friendship. A hard man, with a sharp tongue and a
short temper, is a local misfortune, diffusing discomfort wherever he
treads. I know entire towns which never had a genial man in
them--where every speech is an attack, every suggestion a suspicion, and
every meeting a conflict. Co-operation in these places is always
rheumatic and unhappy--labouring under a sort of suppressed social gout.
Not that I object to grumblers; if they have any sense they are an
uncomfortable kind of benefactors. No English society would do
without them. They act as a sort of Spanish muleteer--they prick
slow animals with long ears over rough places. It must be confessed
they are rather apt to overdo it, and make the patient, steady-working,
good-natured animal bolt, and then they ruin everything.
5. To constantly remember that there is no one,
not a fool who would not be wiser and better than he is, had he the
choice; and that the disagreeable, the wrong-headed, and the base are to
be regarded as unfortunate rather than hateful. Leigh Hunt well
expressed this when he said, "Let us agree to consider the errors of
mankind as proceeding more from defect of knowledge than defect of
goodness." Those who learned this, and those alone, have given
permanence to the co-operative movement. Those who never knew it, or
who, knowing it, have forgotten it, flounder for ever between hatred and
hope.
Long before the Welsh reformer, Robert Owen, was born,
Goldsmith had said, without censure, that "had Cæsar
or Cromwell exchanged countries, the one might have been a sergeant and
the other an exciseman." Owen did but suggest the undeniable
conclusion that in such case Cromwell would have been a Pagan and Cæsar
a Puritan; and therefore co-operators should meet in stores or communities
men of every sect, without hostility or dislike--since particular faiths
are to be honoured as far as they make men into brethren, and are to be
accepted by all who deem them true; while their special varieties are to
be equally regarded as arising in geographical or chronological accidents,
and not to be ascribed to sin. Co-operation would be impossible if
its disciples stooped to sectarian antipathies and spoke of each other
with the bitterness with which Sir John Bowring found the Chief Priest of
the Samaritans of Sychar speaks of the Jews. It was the knowledge
given to co-operators of the human burden of inherited incapacity that
imparted to them that great strength of patience and charity of judgment
which enabled their societies to endure, while the retaliating and fiercer
political and religious parties around them fought themselves out.
Those who look may see that the same nature is master of us all; that
individual man and diversified races, every sect and every opinion, every
passion and every act, are the product of a tireless destiny, which went
before, and of circumstances which follow after, besetting us at every
step--now inspiring the lofty, anon inflaming the base, making men objects
of gladness or pity; saving the high, who know it, from pride; protecting
the low from scorn and despair; striking or serving us, just as we are
wise, to study the ways and observe the methods of Nature. Those who
learn this know no more haste or apathy, foolish hatred or foolish
despair.
Co-operators will never remain leal and true to their society
unless a foundation which never gives way is laid in the understanding.
You cannot command unity, no exhortation will produce it. By mere
business sense a member will put up with some failure or loss, or with
inferior commodities at times, for the advantage which can be had in the
main by holding together. By mere business sense he will not expect
too much; he will know that success comes little by little, and generally
arrives late and takes disagreeable caprices on the way. By mere
business sense a man may be found in his place on dividend day. But
more than this will be wanted to make him a pleasant, ardent, and
continuous associate. If he is made aware that wrong-headed people
mostly had that twist before they were born--that the querulous man has
vinegar nerves, which he would be glad to exchange for the olive-oil
sort--that a conceited associate has gas on the brain which inflates all
his faculties and makes him think they are solid because they feel big--he
will be tolerant and steadfast when others turn aside offended. Half the
irritation we feel at the errors and angular ways of others arises from
forgetting that we ourselves are not infallible, and have stupid and
ungracious intervals like others.
6. A fool cannot be a co-operator, and since
those who know everything do not remember it always, every one should be
instructed and kept instructed in what he is expected to act upon.
Co-operators have made money by their method of business, they have won
honours by being the first of the working class who cared for
self-education as a higher form of property. Aristipus having
counselled a father to seek a good tutor for his son, was asked what would
that amount to? He answered, "A hundred crowns." The father,
thinking the sum large, replied that "such a sum might buy him a slave."
"Well," said Aristipus, "bestow your money so and you shall have two
slaves, the one your ill-bred son and the other he whom you buy for your
money." [207]
The Church for a long time disliked education as tending to
make the lower orders unmanageable, and the Dissenters feared it as making
them carnal-minded--not seeing that the intellectual must always be more
spiritual than the ignorant; but the Co-operators had no dislike of it, no
misgiving about it. It was to them a means of self-defence. In
1835 Mr. Owen announced that he had received £500 for the purpose of
"commencing a school on the most scientific principles for the children of
co-operators and £2,000 more were to be had to extend a knowledge of
sciences among the people." The co-operators made schools for
mechanics popular. Sixty years ago co-operators were in advance of
the nation now, in proposing the best instruction for the humblest.
Knowledge is the same thing to the understanding as the eye
is to the body. Knowledge is the sight of the mind. All
knowledge which throws light on what a man has to do is of the nature of
outside help to him. A mind of few ideas is as a short lever: it can
move only little things; while a mind of many ideas has a longer leverage,
and can move larger obstacles out of its way. Thus knowledge of the
right kind is plainly a good investment.
Every human society in which life and property were in daily
peril has found law and order worth paying for. Those who believe
that things will last their time still have misgivings for their children.
It was one of Mr. Owen's practical merits that he foresaw
that considerations for the security of society in the future, paid in the
present. He had not, like Fairfax, the opportunity of being a king,
but he might have been known as the richest of manufacturers had he not
preferred something higher.
Co-operators knew that it was the want of intelligence that
kept up ugliness in life. Beauty in art, order in cities, grace of
action, good manners, all pay; only few persons know them as things of
value. One reason is that the majority of persons never have the
means of buying perfect things. They are obliged to do without them,
and naturally do not regard them as otherwise they would. Persons
who have anything to spend and only spend it in buying mere sensual
pleasure, have the minds of animals, not the minds of men.
Scientific knowledge and literary knowledge is now provided more or less.
Board Schools, Art Schools, Science Classes, Technical and other colleges
are now open to working men. But education in probity, in
self-possession, in courtesy, in pride of workmanship, in public spirit,
in public duty, in citizenship, where are they taught? Co-operators
can only acquire such knowledge by keeping Libraries, News Rooms, Lecture
Halls at their own command, and for their own use. A recent writer
has shown that in Civil Service Examinations none are examined in
manliness, good sense, or the elements of personal character.[208]
Mr. Brudenell Carter has proved that there is no over-work within the
limits of daily strength. Within those limits work is a condition of
health. The idle die of idleness. Many more than are imagined
die of acquired stupidity. Of course there are a good many people
who do not need to acquire stupidity, they always have a stock on hand.
He is base who, having principles he knows to be useful to others, does
not endeavour to diffuse them; and since Co-operation becomes more
profitable as more persons engage in it, it is want of sense not to extend
it.
Co-operation is liable, in one place or other, to be overrun
by those who see with selfish eyes an escape from misery with money in it,
and see nothing else in it. Co-operation, like the corn-laden
caravans of merchants in the desert, is seized upon by marauding bands,
who carry off treasures intended for honest sale. No sooner is it
discerned that Co-operation creates wealth than swarms of mercenaries
swoop down upon it, to avail themselves of it as a means of gain, caring
nothing for the social education and equality it was intended to promote.
If no educational fund was devised in the infancy of a
society, often no will is strong enough, no reason can prevail, to retrace
the deplorable step. Ignorance grows upon a society as age upon an
individual. It stiffens its limbs, it bows its head, it dims its
sight, it enfeebles its mind, until it retains nothing but the courage of
cupidity; and to gratify that it walks in ignoble ruts all its days.
Such a society may grow, but it has no soundness; its largeness is
puffiness, and a shock of adversity may bring it at once under the hands
of the fiscal coroner who sits in the Bankruptcy Court. As it
commanded no respect in its day, no one mourned its demise. Since
you cannot make co-operators out of simpletons, it is prudent to take care
that they do not overrun the society. Cæsar,
we are told, lamented that he could proceed no faster on his victorious
march than the asses who carried his baggage could travel. The
progress of most societies is often retarded by the same kind of animals.
The best directors are always hampered by want of more intelligence among
the members. The ignorant do not understand their own interest, nor
how to support those who do. Stores whose members are unvaccinated
with business intelligence are sure to break out with the smallpox of
ignorance sooner or later; some have it in a very bad form, and some die
of it. Lectures and literature must be supplied for information.
The brain, like the body, is starved if not fed with ideas. The
thought is thin, the language is lean, the logic is limp, the
illustrations rheumatic, and can hardly stand upright.
The co-operator cannot, like the theologian, increase the
income of the working class by prayer. He works by human
arrangements, economy, and sagacity, and it is only those who have
confidence in these means that have enthusiasm in extending Co-operation.
It was the first murderer, Cain, who asked, "Am I my brother's keeper?"
The co-operator cannot keep his brother, but he has a strong interest in
enabling his brother to keep himself, and he knows the way, and knowing
it, if he does not exert himself to make it known to others, who may be
lost through not seeing it, he is a murderer by his neglect. |